|
Perils
of the Debt-Propelled Economy
By
Henry C K Liu
This article appeared
in Asia
Times Online on September 14, 2002
Economics is a complex
subject. Any subject, however complex,
if looked at in the right way, will become even more complex. This fact
baffles many experts who tend to avoid small errors meticulously while
sweeping on to grand fallacy.
One of the shortcomings
of economics is the inadequate
attention paid to it as a behavioral science. The problem can be traced
to the neoclassical concept of the economic man who is supposed to act
rationally in his own interest which in a money economy is generally
defined rather simplistically as financial gain. Economics is obviously
more than finance, and economic well-being is not synonymous with
financial gain. Modern economics of course deals with the problem of
human behavior with some sophistication, albeit always through the back
door, and always equating self-interest with rational individual
response to pricing. A market economy is coordinated through the price
system operating on the principle of marginal utility.
Economists construct
indifference curves to show consumer
preferences. In economics, the effect on consumption of a pure change
in price is shown in an income-compensated demand curve (also known as
a Hicksian demand curve after economist John Hicks - 1904-89). A
Marshallian demand curve (after economist Alfred Marshall - 1842-1924)
is based on the concept of marginal utility. Marginal utility is
observed only through choices. Marginal utility in consumption is
simply a problem of choosing the bundle of goods that maximizes a
buyer's utility, subject to the income constraint - the requirement
that the bundle the consumer chooses costs no more than the buyer's
disposable income.
Yet the demand for
goods is affected by human behavior. A
good whose consumption increases when its price goes up is called a
Giffen good, after Robert Giffen, a 19th-century English statistician,
who noted that Irish peasants bought more potatoes when the price of
potatoes rose. This contradicted the law of demand, one of the basic
laws of economics. For the poor Irish peasants, potatoes, as the main
staple, took up a huge share of their income. If the price of potatoes
went up, the share of their income available to purchase other foods
would shrink markedly, forcing them to consume more potatoes to make up
the difference.
Giffen goods are also
necessary for conspicuous consumption.
When high-price items go up further in price regularly, such as art
objects, more buyers will enter the market, bidding up prices even
more. Tulip bulbs during the speculative bubble in Holland in the 17th
century were overpriced Giffen goods. The stock market is full of
Giffen goods. When a share price goes up, it attracts more buyers. Real
estate is often a Giffen good, particularly in places like Hong Kong
where the real-estate market is fundamentally controlled by the
government through control of the supply of land.
When housing prices
rise over long periods, more buyers enter
the housing market. The increased demand created by anticipated price
appreciation more than offsets the fall in demand caused by price
increases. And price deflation in housing creates a downward spiral of
shrinking demand, a phenomenon easily observed in recent years all over
Asia, from Tokyo to Hong Kong to Singapore. Public health and
commercial medicine have characteristics of Giffen goods. When the
price of medicine rises, more people tend to get ill due to less
preventive use of medicine, causing aggregate demand for medicine to
rise.
An inferior good is a
good that one buys less of when one's
income rises, because one can afford a superior good by comparison,
even if the inferior good may also rise in price. During periods of
prosperity, when income rises generally faster than prices, inferior
goods are separated from Giffen goods. During periods of recession,
when income falls generally while prices remain the same or continue to
rise, inferior goods and Giffen goods tend to merge. A Giffen good must
be an inferior good, but most inferior goods are not Giffen goods.
Credit drives the
economy, not debt. Debt is the mirror
reflection of credit. Even the most accurate mirror does violence to
the symmetry of its reflection. Why does a mirror turn an image right
to left and not upside down as the lens of a camera does? The
scientific answer is that a mirror image transforms front to back
rather than left to right as commonly assumed. Yet we often accept this
aberrant mirror distortion as uncolored truth and we unthinkingly
consider the flawed reflection in the mirror as a perfect
representation.
Similarly, we
reflexively accept as exact fidelity the
encrypted labels assigned to our thoughts by the distorting mirror of
language. Such habitual faulty acceptance is consequential because it
is through language that ideas are transmitted and around language that
culture develops.
In the language of
economics, credit and debt are related but
not the same. In fact, credit and debt operate in reverse relations.
Credit requires a positive net worth and debt does not. One can have
good credit and no debt. Too much debt lowers credit rating. When one
understands credit, one understands the main force behind the modern
economy, which is driven by credit and stalled by debt. Behaviorally,
debt distorts marginal utility calculations and rearranges disposable
income. Thus debt turns more commodities into Giffen goods and creates
what US Federal Reserve Board chairman Alan Greenspan calls "irrational
exuberance", the economic man gone mad.
Human behavior is
complex beyond the measurement of price.
Price alone is not sufficient to influence market behavior. Karl Marx
dealt with the concept of fetish as a factor in demand as expressed in
price.
Education is a classic
dilemma. Economics literature has
never dealt satisfactorily with education, being unable to decide
whether it is consumption or investment or both. It has done similarly
with health care and environmental preservation. If these endeavors are
consumption, the law of scarcity dictates that society cannot afford
too much of them. If they are investment, then supply-side theory would
conclude the more the better. If they are both consumption and
investment, there should be a limitless upward spiraling supply/demand
symbiosis. One could not possibly have an over-educated society or
over-healthy population or an over-clean environment, if being more
educated, more healthy and more clean is deemed economically productive
and thus financially profitable.
It is obvious that debt
changes human behavior. A little debt
reinforces responsibility. The US social system of private property is
built on the notion that homeowners with a life-long mortgage are
better citizens than renters. People tend to take better care of their
homes and plant roots in their communities if they "own" their homes,
even though 90 percent of the purchase value is in debt that is not
expected to be paid off until three decades later.
On the other hand, it
is clear that excessive debt encourages
irresponsibility. The borrower may develop an irresistible incentive to
walk away from his debt if he perceives the debt to be beyond his
ability to repay, or the cost of the debt to exceed its benefits. Even
a central bank, which is the domestic lender of last resort, is wary of
the problem of moral hazard, that commercial banks within its system
would lend irresponsibly if they knew that their lending errors would
be bailed out by the central bank.
The US bankruptcy
regime is designed to give trapped debtors
a fresh start from distressed debt to reestablish credit. Unlike
European precedents, one cannot be jailed in the United States for
failing to pay one's debt, unless criminal fraud is involved. In fact,
there is a legal concept of lender liability, based on which a
distressed debtor can sue the lender for damages for lending money
irresponsibly that led the debtor into financial trouble.
Lender liability is
embodied in common and statutory law
covering a broad spectrum of claims surrounding predatory lending. It
is a key concept in environmental-cleanup litigation. If a lender
knowingly lends to a borrower who is obviously unable to make
reasonable beneficial gain from the use of the funds, or causes the
borrower to assume responsibilities that are obviously beyond the
borrower's capacity, the lender not only risks losing the loan without
recourse but is also liable for the financial damage to the borrower
caused by such loans. For example, if a bank lends to a trust client
who is a minor, or someone who had no business experience, to start a
risky business that resulted in the loss not only of the loan but of
the client trust account, the bank may well be required by the court to
make whole the client.
In the United States,
although predatory lending is not
defined by federal law, and various states define abusive lending
differently, it usually involves practices that strip equity away from
a homeowner, or equity from a company, or condemn the debtor into
perpetual indenture. Predatory or abusive lending practices can include
making a loan to a borrower without regard to the borrower's ability to
repay, repeatedly refinancing a loan within a short period of time and
charging high points and fees with each refinance, charging excessive
rates and fees to a borrower who qualifies for lower rates and/or fees
offered by the lender, or imposing new unjustifiably harsh terms for
rolling over existing debt. Predation breaks the links between an
economy's aggregate resource endowment and aggregate consumption and
between the interpersonal distribution of endowments and the
interpersonal distribution of consumption.
The choice by some to
be predators decreases aggregate
consumption, both because the predators' resources are wasted and
because producers sacrifice production by allocating resources to
guarding against predators. Much of welfare economics is based on the
concept of Pareto Optimum, which asserts that resources are optimally
distributed when an individual cannot move into a better position
without putting someone else into a worse position. In an unjust global
society, the Pareto Optimum will perpetuate injustice.
Now, there is a close
parallel in most Third World debts and
International Monetary Fund (IMF) rescue packages to the above
predation examples where sophisticated international bankers knowingly
lend to dubious schemes in developing economies merely to get their
fees and high interest, knowing that "countries don't go bankrupt", as
Walter Wriston of Citibank famously proclaimed. The argument for Third
World debt forgiveness contains large measures of lender liability and
predatory lending. Debt securitization allows these bankers to pass the
risk to the credit markets, socializing the potential damage after
skimming off the privatized profits.
Credit is reserved
financial resources ready for deployment.
Debt basically is unearned money secured with a promise to repay the
principal sum plus interest with optimistically anticipated earned
money in the future, assuming, for example, that the borrower will not
become unemployed through no fault of his own or a business will not be
adversely affect by unanticipated shifts in business paradigm, or an
economy will not be destroyed by global financial contagion.
Paying down debt with
new debt is a Ponzi scheme - the
likelihood of its exposure is inversely proportional to its scale of
operation. More and more critics are calling the Enron debacle a Ponzi
scheme, in that the company filed for bankruptcy even though, for
almost a decade up to a few weeks before its bankruptcy filing, many in
high places were hailing Enron as the new innovative business model.
Neoliberal economist
Paul Krugman publicly hailed Enron as a
shining example of free-market entrepreneurship in what he called "a
love letter to free markets". He served on its prestigious advisory
board for a annual fee of US$50,000. Neoconservative Weekly Standard
editor Bill Kristol received $100,000 from the same Enron advisory
board, while contributing editor Irwin Stelzer praised Enron for
"leading the fight for competition".
On November 13, 2001,
two weeks before Enron filed bankruptcy
on December 2, the Baker Institute honored Greenspan with its Enron
Prize, which the official press release said "gives recognition to
outstanding individuals for their contributions to public service. The
prize is made possible by a generous gift from the Enron Corp ... one
of the world's leading electricity, natural-gas and communications
companies. Among the previous recipients of the Enron Prize are Colin
Powell, current US secretary of state; Mikhail Gorbachev, former
president of the Soviet Union; Nelson Mandela, the first black
president of South Africa; and Georgian President Eduard Shevardnadze."
Enron officials have
since acknowledged that the company has
purposely overstated its profits by billions of dollars since 1997 and
has disguised billions in debt as revenue through structured finance
via offshore special-purpose vehicles. Top Enron executives cashed out
more than $1 billion in company stocks when they were near their peak
price of more than $80. In addition, nearly 600 employees deemed
critical to Enron's operations received more than $100 million in
bonuses in November 2001 while the company was on the brink of
bankruptcy. Some commitment to public service.
On the corporate level,
debt inevitably alters management
behavior. Leverage increases profit margin on successful business
plans. As Henry Kravis, king of the leveraged buyout, famously said:
"Debt can be an asset. Debt tightens a company." To less creative
minds, debt is still a liability, not an asset. But debt also
exaggerates losses when business plans fail. In the US financial
system, bankruptcy is a legal if not painless way to refute debt. The
comfort to lenders is that equity investors are wiped out first before
the lenders' various collateralized positions are endangered.
Banks used to be the
sole intermediaries of debt. For this
reason, a central bank was formed to supervise and provide liquidity to
the banking system. Thus a central bank came into existence in the
United States in 1913 on the assumption that the existence of a healthy
banking system is in the national interest. And to protect the national
interest, the central bank, which in the US version is a government
institution privately owned by the banks in the Federal Reserve system,
is allowed to act as lender of last resort to the nation's commercial
banks with public money, or more accurately, through government
authority to create fiat money.
Thus regulation on
banks is a fair quid pro quo, a social
contract. Bank deregulation without corresponding raising of the
threshold for central-bank bailout is a direct breach of this social
contract. If for the good of the nation banks cannot be allowed to
fail, they should also not be allowed to deregulate.
More ominous, the US
credit system has broken through the
banking system - the bulk of debt now is intermediated through the
unregulated credit markets by debt securitization. Securitization acts
as more than just providing a vehicle for investment in debt
instruments. It restructures simple debt into complex, hybrid
instruments sliced infinite ways until the original debt is beyond
recognition.
Debt securitization is
guerrilla warfare against a sound
credit system. Debt proceeds can be disguised as current income,
distorting the financial performance of the debtor. In these brave new
credit markets, the government is generally only an interested
bystander, so far quite unwilling to regulate even over-the-counter
(OTC) derivative trading by banks, which are suppose to be regulated,
with an "if I don't smoke, someone else will" mentality.
OTC derivatives are
traded off exchanges, directly between
counterparties, and as such are not subject to disclosure rules. Adding
estimated data from the Bank for International Settlements for OTC
derivatives to published figures for exchange-traded derivatives, the
total notional principal balance of the reported derivatives market in
June 2001 was $119 trillion, about four times the gross domestic
product (GDP) of the Organization of Economic Cooperation and
Development (OECD) countries and twice the value of global trade. The
amount unreported remains unknown.
This shows that
derivatives performed more than a hedge
function, as apologists claim. Derivative trading has become a profit
center for banks and non-bank financial institutions. True, the
notional principal amount is never at risk, because no principal
payments are exchanged. The interest payments that are linked to that
notional principal amount are at risk. A loss on a derivative contract
becomes possible when (a) interest rates or commodity prices move in a
direction that makes the contract more or less valuable, and (b) the
counterparty on the other side of the contract defaults. Derivatives
credit exposure is the present value of the cost of restoring the
economic value of a contract should a counterparty default.
All kinds of street
rumors are flying at this very moment
that one of the world's biggest banks is exposed to derivative trades
that would cause serious counterparty credit problems if the market
capitalization of this bank should fall below a triggering level, or
the price of commodities or interest rates should move against its
derivative positions. Because there is no way to dispel or confirm such
rumors, and the bank involved remains tight-lipped about its true
financial conditions, the uncertainties weigh down on the economy.
There is ample evidence
that the level of interest rates does
not always control the aggregate level of debt in an economy, popular
expectations notwithstanding. When interest rates are high, they often
merely reflect the systemic credit-unworthiness of borrowers as a group
or the high risk assumed by lenders collectively. High interest rates
in fact create more incentive for both lenders and borrowers to take
higher risk to shoot for the higher returns needed to meet higher
interest cost. High interest rates also direct money to more desperate
borrowers. As William Zeckendorf, the bankrupt real-estate tycoon, once
said: "I'd rather be alive at 30 percent interest than be dead at 3
percent."
However, interest rates
do affect the distribution of credit
in the economy. When rationed by interest rates, debt actually puts
money to work for those who need it most desperately, and not
necessarily the highest and best use in the economy, or where it is
socially needed most. Debts at high interest rates can only be
justified by high risk, which tends to destabilize the economy. Debt
securitization actually lowers systemic credit quality by socializing
risk across the whole system rather than concentrating it on singular,
isolatable defaults.
The US Federal
Reserve's fixation on interest-rate policy as
the sole tool of regulating monetary policy is increasingly taking on
the look of shadow boxing, with declining effect on the economy. As
chairman Greenspan is fond of saying: "Bad loans are made in good
times." As interest rates are artificially raised by Fed action to
tighten money supply, distressed borrowers with bad loans made in good
times will need to borrow more, thus enlarging the credit pool,
defeating the Fed's purpose of a tight monetary policy. As interest
rates are artificially lowered by Fed action to stimulate a slowing
economy, banks raise their credit threshold to compensate for the
narrowing of rate spread, thus reducing the number of qualified
borrowers and shrinking aggregate loan volume. This is known as the Fed
pushing on a credit string.
Credit rationed by
interest rates also discourages economic
democracy, since the poor generally find it much harder to obtain or
afford credit. The poor also do not have the sophistication to
participate in structured finance. There is much truth is the saying
that it is not how much you own, it is how much you owe that measures
how rich or financially powerful you are.
Debt also encourages
carelessness with money, since lending
implies faith in the borrower's ability to repay in the future. People
tend to be more careful with money they earned in the past in the form
of savings because they remember how hard they had to work for it. In
contrast, debt is based on future earnings, which is deemed easier
money by the existence of debt itself. High interest rates also
encourage high risks to justify the high cost of money.
The problem with debt
is that it needs to be serviced
regularly (except zero coupons, which are discounted from the principal
sum at the outset and cost more and are monitored with bond covenants
and triggers to activate automatic foreclosure). Unlike a credit-driven
economy, a debt-propelled economy will inevitably reach a point where
its ability to service the growing debt is exceeded, unless inflation
stays ahead of interest charges, in which case the banking system will
fail. Thus runaway systemic debt frequently leads to hyperinflation.
Bankruptcy only
relieves the debtor, not the economy. If, as
economist Hyman Minsky claimed, money is created whenever credit is
extended, then the erasure of debt destroys money and shrinks the
economy.
There is a circular
link among deregulation, debt,
overcapacity and bankruptcy. Deregulation has created a havoc of
bankruptcy in the airline, health-care, communication, energy and
finance sectors. Deregulation permits predatory pricing in the name of
competition, which often leads to monopolistic consolidation within
industries. The surviving giants then take on massive debt to acquire
vanquished competitors and to expand capacity in anticipation of
increased demand and soon reach a point where increased sales do not
increase net revenue to offset low margin. Once a company is trapped in
the whirlpool of debt, a downward spiral of low prices and shrinking
revenue will push the cost of debt beyond sustainability, leading to
bankruptcy. This is known as the bursting of the debt bubble.
In March 1980, the
Depository Institutions Deregulation and
Monetary Control Act (DIDMCA) was enacted in the United States. It was
a deregulation initiative by the administration of president Jimmy
Carter aimed at eliminating many of the distinctions among different
types of depository institutions and ultimately removing interest rate
ceiling on deposit accounts. Authority for federal savings and loan
associations to make risky ADC (acquisition, development, construction)
loans was expanded, which ended up with the savings and loan (S&L)
crisis five years later. Deregulation of airlines also began under
Carter, leading to recurring waves of bankruptcy.
Conventional wisdom
suggests that a good credit rating is
necessary to borrow. But the financial world works differently in
reality. A good credit rating is first necessary to issue credit.
Without the ability of some entity to issue credit, no one can borrow.
And since no modern financial institution lends its own money, lenders
must first secure funds wholesale to lend to retail borrowers. For
that, a lender must maintain a good credit rating.
Banks are protected
from this requirement by their discount
window at the central bank, which is backed by the full faith and
credit of the nation, and by Federal Deposit Insurance Corp (FDIC)
insurance. Still, central banks and the Bank of International
Settlement (BIS) set capital and reserve requirements for commercial
banks to assure risk prudence.
GE, the world's largest
non-bank financial conglomerate that
incidentally also manufactures, issues credit at the retail level
through vendor financing, to capture sales for GE products. It gets its
funds wholesale from the commercial paper market, which GE dominates
because it has a good credit rating. When GE credit rating was
downgraded recently, it faced being frozen out of the commercial paper
market, and had to revert back to costly bank credit lines that
adversely affected its interest rate spread and profitability.
When a government
issues currency and circulates money
through the banking system, it is in essence issuing credit to the
economy that it is entitled to receive back in taxes. Government then
spends the tax money on goods and services that the public provides.
The surplus money that is not returned by taxes is government credit
floating around the economy to keep it operating financially.
It is important to
understand that money issued by the
government, unlike private money, is not IOUs from the issuer. Money,
when issued by government as a legal tender, is a credit from the
government good for the payment of taxes, and for settling "all debts,
public and private", as printed plainly on all Federal Reserve notes. A
US dollar is a Federal Reserve note that entitles its holder to
exchange it at any of the six Federal Reserve Banks for another Federal
Reserve note of the same face value, no more and no less, at least
since 1971 when the late president Richard Nixon took the dollar off
the gold standard.
Even before 1971, while
an ounce of gold was officially
pegged at $35 by president Franklin Roosevelt on January 31, 1931, a
domestic holder of a dollar note could only exchange it at a Federal
Reserve Bank for another dollar note, since US citizens were forbidden
by law to own gold. Only foreigners could demand gold for dollar up to
1971.
A government bond,
which on the surface looks like a
government debt, is merely a call on government credit previously
issued, withdrawing dollars from the money supply by providing a
government bond. Government bonds are the living proof that money is
not an IOU from the government, otherwise when government sells or
redeems bonds, it is perpetrating a Ponzi scheme of paying off old debt
with new debt, rather than exchanging debt instruments (bonds) with
credit instruments (dollars).
Sovereign debt is
fundamentally different from corporate
debt. A corporate bond entitles its holder to claim its face value in
dollar notes that the bond-issuing corporation cannot create by itself.
It must earn dollars with the bond proceeds to pay interest on the
bonds. At the time of redemption, if the corporation already spent the
bond proceeds, it must then earn back or sell assets or borrow the
dollars from somewhere to redeem the bond.
In contrast, a
government bond entitles its holder to claim
from a Federal Reserve Bank its face value in dollars that the
government can print at will, even if it already spent the bond
proceeds. The interest on the bond is also paid with dollars of which
the government has an unlimited supply. Part of the dollars that the
government spends will come back from the public in the form of taxes.
The rest will stay in the economy to finance its operations.
So if the government
runs a surplus, meaning it takes in more
tax money than it spends, it drains money from the economy, forcing the
economy to contract. A budget deficit is in essence an injection of
more government credit into the economy.
Private citizens can
own assets, but whenever such assets are
monetized with dollars, one trades those assets for credit from the US
government that other market participants in the economy will accept
because, aside from its status of legal tender as defined by law, it is
good for negotiating tax liabilities.
Technically, a
government never borrows. It issues tax credit
in the form of money. So when former president Ronald Reagan said the
government does not make any money, only the private sector does, he
was merely mouthing conventional wisdom, with no clear understanding of
the true nature of money and credit. In fact, money is all that
government makes. Thus any government that takes on foreign-currency
debt or allows its economy to do so is taking unnecessary risk.
The main function of
sovereign debt is not to make up for any
shortfalls in government funds. Such shortfalls cannot exist by
definition. Rather, sovereign debt instruments act as fundamental
collateral for the nation's credit market. The Fed Open Market Desk
buys and sells government securities to maintain the Fed funds target
rate set by the Federal Reserve Board. The repo (repurchase agreement)
market, which provides overnight and short-term funds for banks,
operates with government securities as collateral.
Thus IMF
conditionalities of reducing sovereign debt by
imposing budget surpluses and price deflation as a cure for a
distressed credit market of excessive foreign debt is merely adding
gasoline to fire.
As a sovereign bond is
redeemed with cash, it is in essence
replacing a call instrument on government credit with government
credit. When government securities are withdrawn and cash floods the
economy, the debt market shrinks because the amount of collateral
shrinks and the amount of cash increases, reducing the need for credit,
and the economy contracts with cash inflation, unless the cash is
immediately recirculated as private debt or investment.
The reason that the
market monitors the Fed funds rate as an
indication of Fed policy is that the Fed funds rate closely tracks
another rate, the repo rate, that the Fed Open Market Desk actively
influences during most market days. Every business-day morning at 11:45
Eastern Standard Time, the Fed announces what it intends to do (buying
or selling government securities with an agreement to reverse the
transaction later) in the repo market to keep the repo rate close to
the Fed funds target rate set by the Fed. Changes in the repo rate are
normally quickly followed by changes in the Fed funds rate. Thus,
indirectly, the Fed appears to influence the federal funds rate through
its impact upon the repo rate.
Non-monetarists
subscribe to the view that Fed easing means
the Fed lowers interest rates. But they are not specific about how
these rates are lowered are how the Fed should go about doing this.
There are often periods (such as 1990-91) when interest rates dropped
but money growth also fell. Non-monetarists (and market participants)
view periods like this as Fed easing episodes, while monetarists argue
that these are (implicitly) periods of Fed tightening. Thus it is clear
that interest rates by themselves do not always determine the money
supply.
Since all private debts
in a money economy are anchored by
government credit, through what economists called high-power money
(money created by the Fed through the increase of the total reserves in
the banking system, so called because it would be multiplied manifold
through the money-creation power of commercial bank loans), credit in
an economic democracy should not be rationed by interest rates to the
highest bidder, but by national purposes or social needs.
Credit in fact is a
financial public utility, much like air
and water, and it should be equally accessible to all, not just the
rich. Government loan guarantees for students and house mortgages for
low- and moderate-income groups and loans to small business are based
on this principle.
For example, the US
National Housing Act was enacted on June
27, 1934, as one of several economic-recovery measures of the New Deal.
It provided for the establishment of a Federal Housing Administration
(FHA). Title II of the Act provided for the insurance of home mortgage
loans made by private lenders, taking the risk in lending to low income
borrowers off the private lenders. Title III of the Act provided for
the chartering of national mortgage associations by the administrator.
These associations were to be independent corporations regulated by the
administrator, and their chief purpose was to buy and sell the
mortgages to be insured by the FHA under Title II.
Only one association
was ever formed under this authority on
February 10, 1938, as a subsidiary of the Reconstruction Finance Corp,
a government corporation. Its name was National Mortgage Association of
Washington, and this was changed that same year to Federal National
Mortgage Association (Fannie Mae). By amendments made in 1948, Title
III became a statutory charter for Fannie Mae.
Before the Great
Depression, affording a home was difficult
for most people in the United States. At that time, a prospective
homeowner had to make a down payment of 40 percent and pay the mortgage
off in three to five years. Until the last payment, borrowers paid only
interest on the loan. The entire principal was paid in one lump sum as
the final "balloon" payment.
During the 1920s boom
time in real estate, a rudimentary
secondary mortgage market was established. The stock-market crash of
1929 ended the real-estate boom and forced many private guarantee
companies into insolvency as home prices collapsed. As economic
conditions worsened, more and more people defaulted on mortgages
because they couldn't come up with the money for the final balloon
payment or to roll over their mortgage because of low market value of
their homes.
To help lift the
country out of the Depression, Congress
created the FHA through the National Housing Act of 1934. The FHA's
insurance program protected mortgage lenders from the risk of default
on long-term, fixed-rate mortgages. Because this type of mortgage was
unpopular with private lenders and investors, Congress in 1938 created
Fannie Mae to refinance FHA-insured mortgages.
As soldiers came home
from World War II, Congress passed the
Serviceman's Readjustment Act of 1944, which gave the Department of
Veterans Affairs (VA) authority to guarantee veterans' loans with no
down payment or insurance premium requirements. Many financial
institutions considered this arrangement a more attractive investment
than war bonds.
By revision of Title
III in 1954, Fannie Mae was converted
into a mixed-ownership corporation, its preferred stock to be held by
the government and its common stock to be privately held. It was at
this time that Section 312 was first enacted, giving Title III the
short title of Federal National Mortgage Association Charter Act.
By amendments made in
1968, the Federal National Mortgage
Association was partitioned into two separate entities, one to be known
as the Government National Mortgage Association (Ginnie Mae), the other
to retain the name Federal National Mortgage Association (Fannie Mae).
Ginnie Mae remained in the government, and Fannie Mae became privately
owned by retiring the government-held stock. Ginnie Mae has operated as
a wholly owned government association since the 1968 amendments. Fannie
Mae, as a private company operating with private capital on a
self-sustaining basis, expanded to buy mortgages beyond traditional
government loan limits, reaching out to a broader income cross-section.
By the early '70s,
inflation and interest rates rose
drastically. Many investors drifted away from mortgages. Ginnie Mae
eased economic tension by issuing its first mortgage-backed security
(MBS) guarantee in 1970. Investors found these guaranteed MBSs highly
attractive. Also in 1970, under the Emergency Home Finance Act,
Congress chartered the Federal Home Loan Mortgage Corp (Freddie Mac) to
buy conventional mortgages from federally insured financial
institutions. The legislation also authorized Fannie Mae to purchase
conventional mortgages. Freddie Mac introduced its own MBS program in
1971.
In the early 1980s, the
US economy spiraled into deep
recession. Interest rates and housing prices were high, while income
growth was stagnant. The US economy faced a dual problem of income
deficiency and money devaluation. In this poor housing environment,
Ginnie Mae, Fannie Mae and Freddie Mac all created programs to handle
adjustable-rate mortgages. The Ginnie Mae guaranty is backed by the
full faith and credit of the United States. Today, Ginnie Mae
guaranteed securities are one of the most widely held and traded MBSs
in the world. Ginnie Mae has guaranteed more than $1.7 trillion in
MBSs. Historically, 95 percent of all FHA and VA mortgages have been
securitized through Ginnie Mae. Ginnie Mae is a guarantor, a surety.
Ginnie Mae does not issue, sell, or buy MBSs, or purchase mortgage
loans.
Fannie Mae operates
under a congressional charter that
directs it to channel its efforts into increasing the availability and
affordability of home ownership for low-, moderate- and middle-income
Americans. Yet Fannie Mae receives no government funding or backing,
and it is one of the nation's largest taxpayers as well as one of the
most consistently profitable corporations in America. The company has
evolved to become a shareholder-owned, privately managed corporation
supporting the secondary market for conventional loans. It continues to
operate under a congressional charter with oversight from the US
Department of Housing and Urban Development and the US Treasury.
Fannie Mae has two
primary lines of business: Portfolio
Investment, in which the company buys mortgages and MBSs as
investments, and funds those purchases with debt, and Credit Guaranty,
which involves guaranteeing the credit performance of single-family and
multi-family loans for a fee.
Its Portfolio
Investment business includes mortgage loans
purchased throughout the US from approved mortgage lending
institutions. It also purchases MBSs, structured mortgage products and
other assets in the open market. The corporation derives income from
the difference between the yield on these investments and the costs to
fund these investments, usually from issuing debt in the domestic and
international markets. Fannie Mae has $3.46 trillion in MBSs
outstanding today.
The corporation
accomplishes its mission to provide products
and services that increase the availability and the affordability of
housing for low-, moderate- and middle-income Americans by operating in
the secondary rather than the primary mortgage market. Fannie Mae
purchases mortgage loans from mortgage lenders such as mortgage
companies, savings institutions, credit unions and commercial banks,
thereby replenishing those institutions' supply of mortgage funds.
Fannie Mae either packages these loans into MBSs, which it guarantees
for full and timely payment of principal and interest, or purchases
these loans for cash and retains the mortgages in its portfolio.
Fannie Mae is one of
the world's largest issuers of debt
securities, the leader in the $5 trillion US home-mortgage market.
Fannie Mae's debt obligations are treated as US agency securities in
the marketplace, which is just below US Treasuries and above AAA
corporate debt. This agency status is due in part to the creation and
existence of the corporation pursuant to a federal law, the public
mission that it serves, and the corporation's continuing ties to the US
government. It benefits from the appearance, though not the essence, of
being backed by government credit.
Fannie Mae debt
obligations receive favorable treatment from
a regulatory perspective. Fannie Mae securities are "exempted
securities" under the laws administered by the US Securities and
Exchange Commission to the same extent as US government obligations.
Also, Fannie Mae debt qualifies for more liberal treatment than
corporate debt under US federal statutes and regulations and, to a
limited extent, foreign overseas statutes and regulations.
Some of these statutes
and regulations make it possible for
deposit-taking institutions to invest in Fannie Mae debt more liberally
than in corporate debt and mortgage-backed and asset-backed securities.
Others enable certain institutions to invest in Fannie Mae debt on par
with obligations of the United States and in unlimited amounts. Fannie
Mae uses a variety of funding vehicles to provide investors with debt
securities that meet their investment, trading, hedging, and financing
needs. Fannie Mae is able to issue different debt structures at various
points on the yield curve because of its large and consistent funding
needs. As the Treasury retires 30-year bonds, agencies have stepped in
to fill the void.
The privatization of
Fannie Mae and Freddie Mac was an
ideological move. It was financially unnecessary and government credit
could have funded the entire low-, moderate- and middle-income
housing-mortgage needs with no profit siphoned off to private
investors. These agency debt instruments played a crucial role in
developing and sustaining the credit markets in the US.
In fact, the funding
risk of both agencies was questioned by
the Wall Street Journal last February 20 in an editorial about Fannie
Mae's and Freddie Mac's safety, soundness and financial management,
characterizing both agencies as risky, fast-growing companies that
"look like poorly run hedge funds", "unduly exposed to credit risk with
large derivative positions", and that they "use all manner of
derivatives" and "are exposed to unquantified counterparty risk on
these positions". Such concerns would have been avoided if both
agencies had been funded with government credit, and the cost of
housing to low-, moderate- and middle-income Americans would have been
lower.
A government credit
economy is different from a private debt
economy in its sustainability. The Japanese economy stagnated for more
than a decade primarily because it shifted from a government credit
economy to a private debt economy in the name of financial
liberalization and market fundamentalism. The Japanese version of
London's Big Bang started the Japanese private debt bubble that
subsequently infected all Asian economies.
The Big Bang in London
refers to deregulation on October 27,
1986, of London-based securities markets, an event comparable to May
Day in the US, marking a major step toward a single global financial
market. May Day refers to May 1, 1975, when fixed minimum brokerage
commissions ended in the US, ushering in the era of discount brokerage
firms and the beginning of diversification by the brokerage industry
into a wide range of financial services using computerization and
advanced communication systems. This started the offering of new genres
of financial products and the emergence of structured finance that made
possible a new private-debt economy that turned quickly into a global
debt bubble. As the US reaped the fleeting benefits of dollar hegemony,
a budget surplus accompanied with sovereign debt reduction merely
pushed more debt on to the private sector to feed the debt bubble.
The most fundamental
aspect of a private-debt economy is that
it cannot sustain a slowdown, even a soft landing. If Greenspan had
been better versed in debt economics, he would have understood that a
debt bubble, unlike the conventional business cycle, cannot survive the
slightest deflation. Inflation is the oxygen for a debt bubble.
Greenspan's attempt to
engineer a soft landing by raising
interest rates to fight pending inflation pre-emptively only
accelerated the debt bubble's burst. His only option was to prevent the
debt bubble from forming by tightening credit quality years ago, but he
chose to rely on the market to exercise its discipline. He rejected the
suggestion of such Wall Street gurus as Henry Kaufman to raise margin
requirements. Instead of discipline, the market gave him an insatiable
appetite for addictive debt, which he had previously called "irrational
exuberance".
Once the bubble was on
its way, Greenspan was on top of a
debt tiger that he could not get off without being devoured by the
beast. It was not the New Economy, it was not the unprecedented
productivity that gave the US its decade-long boom. It was debt.
Without debt, there would have been no New Economy, no dotcom industry,
no telecom explosion, no structured finance, no budget surplus and no
current account deficit or its flip side, capital account surplus.
The 1990s was the debt
decade. Much of the technology was
invented prior to the beginning of the decade of finance capitalism and
became widely applied through debt in the form of vendor finance. The
communication revolution was built on debt that had been accumulated in
the last decade. The greatest invention of the 1990s was more and more
sophisticated debt instruments.
Greenspan warned in
December 1996 about "irrational
exuberance" when the Dow Jones Industrial Average (DJIA) was at 7,000,
that inflation down the road was inevitable unless the Fed started to
raise Fed funds rate pre-emptively. Yet as rates rose, the DJIA rose to
12,000 by 2000, because inflation as measured by the government failed
take into account the wealth effect.
The reason for this was
twofold. Inflation was kept low by
imports and inflation was measured mostly by rising wages but not by
rising asset value. Stock prices doubled and real-estate prices
tripled, but the economy officially did not register inflation because
of low wages and cheap imports. As stock prices rose, the price to
earnings ratio skyrocketed. As the economy inched toward technical full
employment with 4 percent unemployed, Greenspan reflexively raised the
interest rate to cut off anticipated wage-pushed inflation. The high
interest rate adversely affected the earnings of debt-ridden companies.
To boost earnings, companies cut employees, which started the downward
spiral.
Since July 1997, the
risks of protracted global asset
deflation caused by the aftermath of excessive private debt have become
reality, first in the emerging markets and now in the United States.
Neither the IMF nor the Group of Seven (G-7) have been able to deal
effectively with the twin problems of the artificially strong but
debt-driven dollar and the spreading manipulated devaluation of other
national currencies around the globe.
For the affected
nations, the combination of mountains of
foreign-currency debt and massive short-term capital flight through
stock-market collapses, exacerbated by IMF conditionalities of high
interest rates, austerity measures that insisted on reduced government
deficits and sharp currency devaluations coupled with asset deflation,
have led to tragic destruction of hard-earned wealth and a severe drop
of living standards.
Certainly market forces
in a runaway-debt economy have not
created Adam Smith's "universal opulence which extends itself to the
lowest ranks of the people". The only trickling down has been poverty
and misery. In a world of 6 billion people, only about 1,000 currency
traders and a small circle of rich investors in their hedge funds seem
to enrich themselves further through the unbridled manipulation of the
free financial market. Even in advanced economies, workers are misled
to accept low wages as a trade-off for stock options that become
worthless when the debt bubble bursts.
Corporations seduce
share owners with fantasy capital gains
based on debt to replace regular dividend payouts. When market
capitalization of major corporations inflated by debt can fall by 90
percent within a matter of months while top executives can cash out at
peak prices and resign with severance packages worth tens of millions
of dollars, there is no other way to describe the situation than
reversed Robin Hood: robbing the poor to help the dishonest rich.
This view is now shared
by increasing numbers across
ideological spectrums. Economist John Kenneth Galbraith's famous
description of trickling down prosperity was if you feed the horse
enough oats, the sparrows will some day benefit from its droppings. In
finance capitalism, the poor sparrows are crushed by the wheels of the
carriage of debt that the horse pulls.
If debt is
dilapidating, foreign-currency debt, mostly dollar
debt, is deadly. Thus those governments that had been misled by
neoliberals to borrow massive amounts of foreign currency unnecessarily
and subsequently dutifully implemented IMF prescriptions, such as
Brazil, Argentina, Turkey, South Korea and Indonesia, saw their
economies destroyed to the point where recovery may now take decades,
if ever, and only if the poisonous IMF medicine is quickly rejected.
The IMF has now
admitted that it made a "slight mistake" in
dealing with the Asian financial crisis of 1997. It might have been
slight for the IMF, but the cost to the economies of Asia was
horrendous. Trillions of dollars of hard-earned assets and economic
capacities have been destroyed, lost forever. In fact, lives have been
lost, children malnourished, families ruined, governments fallen and
ethnic animosities intensified. The cooperative partnership among
neighboring countries has been undermined and regions destabilized.
This is the direct result of predatory lending followed by predatory
IMF rescues. The operations were technically successful but the
patients died.
Since World War II, the
term "capitalism" has been gradually
displaced by the more benign label of the free market. Capitalism
ceased to be mentioned in most economic literature. In the process,
economists also squeezed out of official dialogues the word
"capitalism", the once-traditional name for the market system, with its
subjective connotation of class struggle between owners, through their
professional managers, and workers, through their trade and industrial
unions, and with its legitimization of the privileges that go with
various levels of wealth.
The word "capitalism"
no longer appears in textbooks for
Economics 101. A Harvard economist, N Gregory Mankiw, author of a
popular new textbook, Principles of Economics, told the New
York Times: "We make a distinction now between positive or descriptive
statements that are scientifically verifiable and normative statements
that reflect values and judgments." A whole new generation of
economists have grown up thinking of "capitalism" only as a historical
term like "slavery", unreal in the modern world of market
fundamentalism.
Capital, when monetized
in dollars, is in essence credit from
government. Capitalism in a money economy is a system of government
credits. Thus a case can be made that in a capitalistic democracy,
access to capital and credit should be available equally to all in
accordance with national purpose and social needs. The anti-statist
posture of neoliberalism is not only logically flawed, but its
glorification of a private-debt economy will inevitably lead to
self-destruction.
September 14, 2002
|
|
|
|
|