|
Critique of Central Banking
By
Henry C K Liu
Part I:
Monetary
theology
Part II:
The European Experience
Part
III-a: The US
Experience
Part III-b: More
on the US
experience
Part III-c:
Still More on
the US Experience
Part
III-d: The Lesson of the
US Experience
Part
IV-a: The
Asian Experience
Part IV-b: The Japanese experience
This article appeared in AToL
on May 31, 2003
The domestic
problems in Japan are caused by its economy's tilt toward export,
compounded by export trade being denominated mostly in dollars, not
yen. Japanese policymakers are quite aware of this unhappy situation
and have been trying to propose a tri-currency (dollar-euro-yen) global
financial architecture since 1997. This proposal has been turned down
repeatedly by the United States. Japan could not open its domestic
market to foreign imports because its does not have a domestic market
to open. In place of a domestic market, Japan has a vertically
integrated distribution system controlled by a few big commercial
combines (keiretsu). Its entire postwar
economy is structured for export.
Prior to World War
II, the entire Japanese economy was structured for
war production. After that war, the Japanese economic infrastructure
was kept intact by US occupation policy but diverted from war
production toward export. The relationship of Japanese banks to their
clients is structurally different than what the New Deal set up for US
banks, with an arm's-length relationship between lenders and borrowers.
Japanese banks own substantial shares of their corporate borrowers,
thus there is little financial advantage in corporate debt foreclosure.
This credit
relationship is natural for a national banking regime and
has evolved to achieve maximum efficiency for financing export
production. Mitsubishi never has to compete for capital or credit the
way General Motors does. It can always get credit at a rate that will
ensure its price competitiveness in the export market. This is also why
Japan is not well equipped to finance new entrepreneur ventures. Sony
and Honda are maverick outsiders in the "Japan Inc" system, as is
Softbank, the new financial giant for the information technology sector.
The reason dollar
assets yield higher returns than yen assets is that
yen assets are not structured for highest returns but for effective
support of the Japanese export regime. Japanese banks are not profit
centers. They are service institutions in support of a national
purpose. In the past decade, however, major US corporations such as GE,
General Motors and Ford have taken on the role of non-bank financial
entities to provide low-cost loans as a key competitive pricing
strategy, bypassing their traditional dependence on banks. Henry Ford
was famously critical of banks as financial predators.
This trend of
subordinating finance to enhance market competitiveness, not for
national purpose but for corporate profit, is the Achilles' heel of the
US economy. While Japan is being put through the wringer by the
adoption of a central banking regime, the US non-bank financial sector
is bypassing the regulatory limits of central banking. This more than
any other factor gives validity to the anticipation that the US economy
will follow the Japanese economy into a decade of deflation and
stagnation, even though the US banks are relatively healthy by Bank for
International Settlements (BIS) standards - unless of course the
Federal Reserve adopts a monetary policy of aggressive inflation
targeting beyond the banking system, with the bailout of LTCM as an
obvious precedent. Fed chairman Alan Greenspan said in a speech before
the Council on Foreign Relations in Washington, DC, last November 19:
"Thus central banks are led to provide what essentially amounts to
catastrophic financial insurance coverage.
Japanese culture,
fundamentally influenced by Chinese culture, views the individual as an
integral part of community and as such, while there is no equality in
Japanese society in the Western liberal sense, the Japanese elite
assumes an innate responsibility for the welfare of the people it
leads. Thus a Japanese corporate leader feels personal shame in the
corporation's misfortune and he is expected to punish himself before he
allows the employees to suffer. US values celebrate individualism as
the basic unit of society and thus put the responsibility of individual
welfare on each person even though the US system has evolved in a way
that the individual is increasingly powerless to control his/her own
destiny. Thus US management would proudly lay off 10,000 employees to
achieve short-term profitability with which to reward executives with
fancy "performance" bonuses. The Fed would righteously use unemployment
to defend the value of money (to fight inflation). It would declare the
ease and immunity with which US business can shed unneeded workers on
short notice as systemic strength. Greenspan has repeatedly criticized
both Japanese and German companies for being "inefficient" because of
the high cost and inflexibility their management faces in shrinking
their workforce on demand.
Acting as postwar
resident emperor, General Douglas MacArthur imposed
"democracy" on Japan. And the Japanese adopted its form without its
essence. From its founding in 1955 and for the next 38 years, Japan's
conservative Liberal Democratic Party (LDP) won all national elections
and selected every prime minister and nearly every cabinet member. From
1955 until 1993, the LDP held power without interruption, while the
Japan Socialist Party (now the Social Democratic Party) acted as a
token opposition force. This political landscape was known as "the 1955
setup". It allowed voters to see an obvious, ongoing struggle between
the LDP and the Japan Socialist Party, notwithstanding under-the-table
agreements. Other democracies have had similarly dominant parties, but
few approach the LDP for longevity in power and complete dominance of
the political scene. In fact, many political scientists have suggested
that the LDP is very similar to the ruling communist parties in
socialist countries.
Then, in 1993, a
political earthquake transformed Japan from a system
of stable one-party rule into one of mercurial political coalitions.
For the decade since 1993, the LDP struggled to regain its position of
dominance and for the most part succeeded. At the start of the new
millennium, the LDP lacked a majority in the House of Councilors, the
upper house of the Japanese Diet, but it is nevertheless strong and
confident once again while the opposition is in disarray.
Politically, Japan
by 1985 found itself needing new national goals,
since it had caught up with the Western industrial powers in production
if not in innovation. Unfortunately, Japanese political leaders failed
to formulate a new national vision. The lack of leadership allowed the
bureaucracy to continue to steer the nation along a traditional but
obsolete path of export dependency, hiding the transfer of national
wealth overseas with a speculative bubble of the 1980s. It was
inevitable that this bubble would burst, as the economic benefits of
this export "success" could not be repatriated back to Japan because of
dollar hegemony. The bubble's burst fueled a distrust of the
bureaucracy that had clung to denial, which continues today.
While it is valid to
fault business and industrial leaders for
management myopia, it should be recognized that they had no choice
beyond playing according to the rules of the game set up by
dysfunctional national policies. The political leadership must bear the
responsibility for failing to set visionary goals for the nation. The
current sentiment in Japan of being at a structural impasse and not
knowing how to move forward in new directions is the direct result of
the lack of focus on national goals for the past two decades.
The Plaza Accord of
1985 on exchange rates forced the yen's climb -
from 242 yen to the dollar before the agreement to as high as 79 yen in
slightly more than a decade. The structural damage of the rise of the
yen had been undeniable. The United States reversed the notion of the
need for stable exchange rates as envisaged by the Bretton Woods
regime, and openly used exchange-rate policy as a way of addressing its
trade imbalance. Instead of addressing its own fiscal irresponsibility,
the US decided to solve its problem by forcing Japan to change its
economic system through an exchange-rate policy. This approach of
achieving a balance of trade through exchange-rate management triggered
unwanted changes not only in the Japanese economy but also in Japanese
society as a whole. Japan is still in the throes of this unwanted
change, and the resulting anxiety has fostered a national sense of
being in a blind fix.
The essence of this
change for the Japanese is their inability to
develop a heightened consciousness of themselves as consumers of the
fruits of their efforts, instead of exporters. The Japanese political
system and administrative apparatus has been heavily weighted in favor
of export production since the end of World War II, while suppressing a
consumer culture. It is a civic pride to produce but not to consume.
The war of export was won by a denial of domestic consumption that
fitted cerebrally the Japanese culture of self-restraint. To overcome
this export fixation, the political system and administrative apparatus
have to change. But culture changes only slowly. Further, the
stagnation of the export economy reinforces the conventional wisdom
that consumption in hard times would be foolhardy and only lead to
financial ruin for the imprudent individual. <>Deregulation
requires that consumers take responsibility for their own decisions.
Thus as Japan takes steps to deregulate its economy, the government
dilutes its power of persuasion to stimulate consumer spending.
Neo-liberals argue that since the government can no longer protect the
individual, Japan needs improved transparency, as embodied in the
principle of disclosure, as an essential condition of a
consumer-oriented society. Yet culture does not change as easily as
government policies or corporate strategies. The flip side is for
government to preserve its tradition of elitist opacity by insulating
the public from economic pain, which was essentially what had happened.
The past decade in
Japan has been one in which the public has been insulated from the
pains of an economic decay that has been largely confined to the
corporate level. It is the opposite of what happened in the United
States, where the pain is felt directly and immediately by the
defenseless public while companies consolidate through downsizing and
merging. <>Both the Meiji
Restoration of 1868 and the socio-economic restructure imposed by
MacArthur after World War II were carried out under pressure from
foreign powers. This latest opening of Japan has been triggered again
by foreign pressure in the form of US-led globalization.
In April 1999, the
Japanese government deregulated foreign-exchange
transactions. After Japan's Big Bang, the country ended up with an open
financial market where foreign banks and brokerages were the dominant
players. If Japanese banks cannot serve the Japanese consumer because
of their structural link to Japan Inc, US banks will.
Globalization in
Asia means new players entering from outside the
region. But resistance is still strong in Japan. Many there, along with
others in Asia, interpret this development as another neo-imperialist
assault by Western economic power as well as Western culture and
values. And they are beginning to oppose it with a revival of
nationalism. In Japan, it takes the form of a revival of the
nationalism of the final years of the Tokugawa shogunate in the 19th
century. Prime Minister Junichiro Koizumi may be Japan's first
internationalist leader who came to power in the name of chauvinism.
Neo-liberals believe
that Japan, along with the rest of Asia, will have
no choice but to make major changes in response to the globalization
process. The trend toward transparency challenges the belief that
keeping certain things concealed is one key to social harmony. The
Western notion of the rule of law is often touted as an indispensable
component of modernization.
Yet Japan is based
on a deep-rooted Confucius culture. In The Analects of
Confucius,
the sage is described as responding to the selfless rule of law by
saying: "In our part of the country, those who are upright act
differently. The father conceals the misconduct of the son, and the son
conceals the misconduct of the father." This embodies the conflict
between legalism and the hierarchical order of Confucianism in ancient
China, a conflict still very much alive in contemporary China. Although
this episode in The Analects concerns the
relationship between parents and children, the application is much
broader to include issues of governance. <>Traditionally,
Asian, including Japanese, law-enforcement officers often let offenders
off with a stern warning if circumstances warrant it. In the Kabuki
drama Kanjincho
(The Subscription List), the official in
charge of the Ataka Barrier Station is charged with capturing the
fugitive Yoshimune. He is so impressed by the efforts of Benkei,
Yoshimune's retainer, to shield his lord that he turns a blind eye and
allows the disguised hero and his retinue to pass. Japan also has
heroes who flout the law, such the chivalrous robber Kunisada Chuji
(1810-50), the Japanese Robin Hood.
Countries vary
considerably as to how rigidly they apply the law.
William Blake said that one law for the lion and the sheep is
oppression. The West has often observed critically that China lacks the
rule of law. In reality, the West merely is not happy with China's
concept of rule of law. Americans also do not think that Japan meets
their standards for genuine rule of law. Asians often describe the US
way as the rule by law rather than of law. There's
nothing in nature that says an advanced modern nation has to be a rigid
constitutional state, and the United States' adherence to that
principle may not be the reason it achieved its measure of power and
influence in the world, among many other factors. Yet, as globalism
proceeds, the rest of the world is compelled to measure its daily
actions against US standards, merely because the US is the sole
superpower.
Exchange-rate
volatility since 1985 has had a huge impact on Japan.
Stock prices have in fact been driven by exchange rates because of
global capital flow and international banking standards. If a two-party
system ever emerges in Japan, it will be based on two political
ideologies: one that believes in free markets and small government, and
another that believes there are flaws in a free-market economy and that
government exists to minimize the resulting disparities in wealth and
help society's weaker members, and that for this Japan needs high
taxes. But Japan is some distance from reaching that point. For the
foreseeable future, a one-party system with two opposing factions is
likely to continue. Nor is the notion that the weak are the
responsibility of the strong, at least within Japanese society, likely
to disappear from Japanese culture.
After World War II,
Japan developed into a country with small
disparities in income, perhaps the smallest of any major economy in the
non-communist world. That helped create a stable society, and it also
took the steam out of calls for a redistribution of wealth or
progressive income-tax regime. Japan has a de facto national socialist
system in the descriptive, non-pejorative sense of the term. There has
always been a voting minority of about 20 percent who are dissatisfied
with the government, but that group does not constitute an identifiable
economic or social class.
Since the end of the
Bretton Woods regime, the relentless Japanese
quest for trade surplus in dollars and not in yen has been a big
mistake. Dollars can no longer be converted to gold and dollars cannot
be spent in Japan. Dollars can only buy dollar assets such as the
Rockefeller Center in New York. The Germans have been making an even
bigger mistake with their quest for trade surplus in dollars. Everyone
accepted deutschmarks before the birth of the euro. Japan and Germany
should have incurred as large a trade deficit in their own currencies
as their trading partners would accept. Trade yields currency. When
export yields another country's currency, it is hard to benefit the
domestic economy with it. It is hard for Americans to understand this
because world trade yields dollars that are usable in the United
States. It is also hard for the rest of the world to understand this
because they did not catch on to the meaning of the dollar being no
longer backed by gold.
Suggestions that
Japan's bad bank loans may now equal almost half of
the country's gross domestic product (GDP) have been greeted with
official denial in Japan but have shaken the markets for more than a
decade. Market estimates of non-performing loans (NPLs) now amount to
237 trillion yen (US$2 trillion), dramatically larger than published
government data indicate. The Financial Services Agency (FSA), the main
regulator, claims that bad loans at the banks total only 18 trillion
yen, or 3 percent of GDP.
The discrepancy is
not from the bank data, but from different rules for
measuring bad loans. In particular, the FSA ignores the effect of
deflation when classifying problem loans. The FSA sorts loans into
"good", "risky" and "bad" categories based on whether a company is able
to pay interest. This classification system, useful in an inflationary
environment, where nominal interest rates are high, is not useful in
Japan's low-interest-rate regime where most companies could make
interest payments - even if their business prospect is so hopeless that
they would never be able to repay their loans. Such companies are
corporate versions of the walking dead.
Bank economists have
suggested that the risk level of a loan should be
judged on whether a company's operating margins are good enough to
repay the loan within term. On this basis, corporate data on listed
companies suggests that more than a third of all bank loans are bad
risks, even though most are not classified as risky by the government.
Japanese banks have already written off bad loans to the equivalent of
13 percent of Japan's GDP in the past decade. There may be another 50
percent of GDP equivalent to go.
Other analysts
dispute this method of loan classification, saying that
Japanese banks have never extended loans on the basis of cash-flow
analysis, but on assets such as real estate. Yet even on this basis,
deflation has eroded asset value. Government officials also argue that
no country in the world calculated bad loans from the ratio of
operating margin to bank lending. The Bank of Japan (BOJ), the central
bank, is uneasy with the fact that the "real" bad-loan problem is
greater than FSA numbers show, given the weak economy and the impact of
deflation. As a central bank, BOJ allegiance is to the value of its
currency, rather than the health of the economy. Central banks take
this view because they believe that the health of the economy depends
on the soundness of money. They reject the notion that the health of
the economy is the basis of a sound currency. Central bankers are not
above arguing that the operation is a success, though the patient died.
Japan's
institutional and economic history has been front and center
mercantilist. Japan does not export to live. It lives to export. Yet
since the Bretton Woods fixed-exchange-rate regime based on a
gold-backed dollar ended in 1971, Japan has been exporting not for
gold, nor for gold-backed dollars. It has been exporting for a fiat
currency called the dollar that the United States can print at will and
at no cost. Japan has been shipping its goods overseas in exchange for
paper that cannot buy anything in Japan. The trade surplus in dollars
is merely pieces of paper than can buy other pieces of paper called US
Treasuries, or share certificates of US companies that compete with
Japanese companies. Or certificates of ownership of dollar assets
outside of Japan that pay dividends in pieces of paper that cannot be
spent in Japan. The conventional wisdom is that Japan must earn dollars
to buy needed imports such as oil and other commodities that Japan does
not produce. But Japan exports way in excess of its import needs.
Notwithstanding the fact that if Japan exports less, it will also need
to import less oil and iron ore, there is no reason Japan needs to have
a trade surplus, or that a trade surplus is of benefit to Japan.
Economist Hyman P
Minsky asserts that an understanding of a country's
institutional and economic history is essential for a clear
understanding of its financial processes. Institutional and historical
realities mean that a country cannot easily escape its relatively rigid
past to join a global system without serious penalty. Japan's trade
surplus in dollars is the serious penalty for its fixation with export
in a trade regime based of another country's fiat currency. The United
States, whose influence on financial globalization is paramount, enjoys
the least upheaval to its national system in the transition to
neo-liberal globalization because the global system is in essence an
extension of the US system. And dollars, the scorekeeping instrument
for world trade, can only be spent in the US on US assets. So no matter
who owns dollars, the economic benefits of the dollar are firmly
focused on the US economy.
Because of the BIS
requirement on capital and loan classification,
Japanese banks continue to suffer from the supportive loans made to
Japanese corporations during the "bubble" era more than a decade
earlier. Such loan policies were not a problem when Japan operated
under a national banking regime. But under a central banking regime,
Japanese banks have become by definition distressed institutions in
deep crisis. Despite the fact that a large proportion of these loans
have turned into NPLs by BIS standards, many Japanese banks have
delayed the recognition of such NPLs until recently. Unlike US banks,
which quickly wrote off their NPLs in the early 1980s to meet domestic
regulatory requirements, though not without great pain to the US
economy and the general public, none of the Japanese banks wrote off
their NPLs until Sumitomo Bank took the lead in March 1995. Since then,
top Japanese banks have begun to write off NPLs, voluntarily following
Sumitomo, albeit only with strong pressure from the global investor
community acting on bank share prices. The reason for this is that the
US central bank can print dollars without directly affecting the
exchange value of the dollars, a phenomenon known as "dollar hegemony",
and the BOJ cannot.
Under a national
banking regime, Japanese banks attracted investors not
because they produce high returns, but because they were part of the
national enterprise that strengthened the Japanese economy. Under a
central banking regime, global investors are interested primarily in
the profit margin of the banks, often to be achieved at the expense of
the economy. When a liquidity trap immobilizes interest-rate policy as
an economic stimulant, there is still an exchange-rate channel by means
of which monetary policy can exert stabilizing effects. This is why
Japan has been trying to push the yen down, not to increase exports,
but to stabilize deflation at home.
The main reasons for
the hesitance of Japanese banks to write off NPLs
can be attributed to the policy indecisiveness of the Ministry of
Finance (MOF), which still holds a view on the function of banks along
national-banking lines. The MOF is reluctant to recognize and address
the NPL problem as defined by a central banking regime, for it sees no
useful purpose in such an exercise. Also, the Japanese tax system does
not permit tax deductions for loan writeoffs. Banks also were deluded
by anticipation of pending economic recovery from counter-cyclical
government fiscal measures. The dual role of banks as shareholders and
creditors of the borrowing entities also presents a disincentive. There
is also the problem of insufficient capital for banks to write off the
loans to satisfy BIS requirements.
The BOJ addressed
the insufficient-capital issue in 1995 by increasing
the nation's money supply to lower interest rates, a move that
increased the net interest income of Japanese banks because of larger
spreads on loans over cost of funds. In this new monetary-policy
environment, many banks were supposed to be able to generate sufficient
profits to write off NPLs. Japan's equity and real-estate bubbles
collapsed within a short time of each other, with equity prices
dropping more than 50 percent in early 1990 and land prices beginning a
long slide downward in 1991. After raising official interest rates to
counteract overheating financial markets, the BOJ began lowering
interest rates from more than 6 percent in March 1991 to 0.5 percent by
October 1995.
Despite this
favorable operating environment for banks, the quality of
Japanese banks' assets continued to deteriorate because of what John
Maynard Keynes identified as a liquidity trap. A liquidity trap is
created when further increases in money supply by the central bank
(monetary base) cannot further affect output, prices, interest rates or
other variables. Increases in the money stock are entirely neutralized
by increases in liquidity preference to hold money.
The idea of a
liquidity trap originated with Keynes during the Great
Depression. Keynes postulated that once the interest rate fell below 2
percent, its effect on monetary expansion might be "push on a string".
While rates might be low, banks might still have difficulty lending
because the low interest-rate spread would reduce credit risk
tolerance. Soon the banks would only lend to those who did not need to
borrow.
Under current
circumstance, the BOJ can stop interest-rate and price
decline by purchasing foreign currencies to push the foreign-exchange
values of the yen down, or by purchasing corporate bonds and stocks, or
other assets. But the BOJ as a central bank is committed to preserve
the market, not to eliminate it. So it sticks with the traditional
central-bank instrument of interest-rate policy. It seeks to control
the price of money rather than prices in general in the economy, making
the liquidity trap a reality.
International
capital markets started to charge a "Japan premium" on
inter-bank loans. In addition, Japanese banks faced difficulty in
complying with BIS capital-adequacy ratio as the depreciation of the
yen increased the value of their overseas assets and liabilities. This
also increased the banks' reluctance to provide loans to less
creditworthy small and medium-sized companies that had no access to
credit markets beyond their main banks. To address the banking and
credit crunch problems, public funds totaling 60 trillion yen (12
percent of GDP) finally were set aside in 1998-99 to recapitalize
banks. Also, the low short-term rates created problem for non-bank
long-term financial institutions, such as insurance companies.
The increasing
number of bankruptcies, as well as the collapse of
Hokkaido Takushoku Bank in November 1997, illustrated the seriousness
of the NPL problem, which is currently estimated to be near $2
trillion. Over the past 18 months, the Japanese government has enacted
laws to use public funds to purchase preferred stock of Japanese banks
in order to provide the banks with the much-needed capital to write off
additional NPLs. The Resolution and Collection Corp (RCC), an agent
established to purchase loan assets and to collect the debt, has been
expanded to purchase NPLs from Japanese banks.
On July 7, 2001,
commenting on the bad-loan problem, Prime Minister
Koizumi was realistic: "I do understand that it is impossible to get
rid of all existing bad loans within two to three years but we are
working on reducing that," he said. "I think it is a bit premature to
say that the government does not have total grip on bad loans. What we
are working on is the bigger issue of the economy." The bigger issue,
of course, is economic growth.
In a government
package released three months earlier, in April 2001,
Japan set a deadline for top banks to eliminate loans to borrowers in,
or at risk of, bankruptcy - worth 11.7 trillion yen - in two years, or
three years for new NPLs. Some estimates valued the problem loans at
banks at as much as 150 trillion yen. The worries about banks have been
a key factor in a prolonged stock market slump. Koizumi warned that
Tokyo stock prices were poised to remain depressed for the time being.
It is worthwhile to note that no serious analyst expected Japan to
resolve its NPLs within two years from 2001.
Japan's government
is in an inescapable debt-death spiral by virtue of
the fact that nominal GDP is falling at an annual rate of about 5
percent. Stabilizing the Japanese government's debt-to-GDP ratio would
require that nominal GDP rises at a rate equal to the interest rate on
its outstanding debt, or about 1 percent. The fact that nominal GDP is
falling at a 5 percent rate means that Japan's debt-to-GDP ratio will
rise at least 6 percent a year, even without a sudden need to
recapitalize insolvent banks. That debt-GDP ratio is now 130 percent,
and at 6 percent a year it will double in just over a decade. That fact
will itself accelerate the collapse of Japanese government bonds unless
deflation is reversed.
Actually, the debt
burden of Japan's government is worse than the 130
percent debt-to-GDP ratio widely reported in the press. First,
accelerating deflation will cause that ratio to rise even more rapidly
as government revenue collapses. Further, the contingent liabilities of
the government, including its responsibilities to protect bank
depositors, will jump abruptly once the increasingly likely crisis in
the banking system emerges.
The Japanese
government possesses assets that could be sold to improve
its ability to deal with large losses in the banking system. The
problem with such sales, for example the sale of government-owned
shares in Japan Tobacco or NTT (Japan's telephone company), is that
they further depress the value of these shares on the stock market.
This is just another example of the dangers of a deflationary
environment in which assets that had been viewed as reserves can no
longer function as liquid reserves because attempts to realize
liquidity further depress their value.
Japanese deflation
gathered pace in the first quarter of 2003 as
year-on-year prices fell 3.5 percent - their fastest drop on record.
The fall may fuel fears that Japan, which has managed to co-exist with
relatively mild deflation since the mid-1990s, could be sliding into an
accelerating deflationary spiral. Japanese prices - as measured by the
gross domestic product deflator, considered a more accurate measure
than the consumer price index, have been falling continuously since
1995. Annual price falls have averaged between 1 and 2 percent for most
of that time. Recent figures showed deflation accelerating in fiscal
2002, a year in which Japan was technically growing out of recession,
to minus 2.2 percent, a record for a full year. The figures were
released along with GDP data showing that growth in the first quarter
2003 fell to almost zero, leading some economists to conclude that the
economy was on the brink of yet another recession. Nominal growth fell
0.6 percent in the March quarter, or minus 2.5 percent on an annualized
basis.
The issue of
deflation has split government officials with disputes
over its causes and disagreement over its effects. Heizo Takenaka, the
new minister of state for economic and fiscal policy and head of FSA,
has acknowledged that falling prices pose a threat but takes the
position that banking reform is need to cure it. He said: "Deflation
remains severe. While pursuing structural reform we must also press on
with efforts to end deflation." On the other hand, Eisuke Sakakibara,
former vice finance minister, also known as Mr Yen, said Japan could
live with mild deflation so long as it prevented the economy tipping
into a destructive spiral of falling prices. He said deflation was the
structural result of global productivity gains and would likely spread
from Japan to the United States and Europe.
Takenaka drew some
comfort from the fact that real growth for fiscal
2002 was 1.6 percent, above the 0.9 percent the government had
predicted. Much of that was based on exports, which have predictably
begun to slow again, and on surprisingly robust consumer spending. In
the first quarter of 2003, consumer spending, which accounts for 60
percent of GDP, rose 0.3 percent quarter on quarter. Real growth of
about 1 percent a year over the past decade meant that the economy was
shrinking in nominal terms. Nominal GDP for fiscal 2002 fell to 499
trillion yen, the first time it has dipped below 500 trillion yen in
eight years. Political pressure had been building against Koizumi to
slow the pace of bank reform to relieve the pain of the corporate
sector, which may lead to the removal of Takenaka.
The yen has been
testing two-year highs against the dollar recently as
investors continued to push the US currency lower on signals from the
new US Treasury Secretary, challenging Japanese resolve to stem yen
strength in the process. The BOJ has not confirmed any action in the
market recently. Following a policy of covert intervention in the first
quarter of 2003, strategists expect the first concrete evidence of any
action in May will come in the bank's figures, published at the end of
the month. The BOJ, however, is believed to have been active in the
market to smooth if not stop the yen's fall.
The longer the yen's
rise goes on, the greater the prospect that
Japanese investors will sell dollars forward, exacerbating the yen's
upward move. It is difficult to stop Japanese funds from hedging their
US exposure. A further risk is that a strong currency could tempt
investors to repatriate funds back to Japan. Japanese investors have
been pouring money abroad on the perception the MOF will continue to
draw a line in the sand on yen strength and if such perceptions are
damaged, an accelerated wave of yen purchases will occur. Thus the
perception that the MOF will let the yen rise will cause the market to
push up the yen.
Japan's population
is poised to decrease at a rapid rate because of
demographics. Aggregate production is also declining because of changes
in labor utilization. Since the main sources of Japan's economic
strength, namely high saving and high investment, remain intact, Japan
is still making heavy investment for the future, but the major thrust
is on upgrading the quality of life and linkage with the Chinese
economy. This linkage with China brings mixed results for Japan. The
positive side is to increase aggregate production but the negative side
is that it causes prolonged deflation. Deflation dampens Japan's import
capacity from the rest of Asia except from China. The outcome is the
rise of Northeast Asia and the relative decline of Southeast Asia. The
deepening economic linkage and continuing political divergence between
Japan and China is also becoming difficult to sustain.
Population is one of
the most important factors in a nation's economy.
When Japan incurs a trade surplus with the United States, an economy
with twice its population, it means that Japanese are consuming at a
lower level than Americans. Since production is a function of the size
of the domestic working population, the decrease in working population
means fewer work-hours each year, which translates into less production
capacity. It will weaken the country's capacity to supply goods and
services both for home consumption and for export. The average number
of work-hours per worker is also decreasing in Japan. Only 13 years ago
in 1990, it was 2,053 hours per year per worker, the highest among the
Organization of Economic Cooperation and Development (OECD) member
countries. Three years ago in 2000, it shrank by 10 percent from the
1990 level to 1,848 hours to the sixth-longest working hours among the
OECD members. The myth of Japan working hard and long hours is now an
anecdote of the past.
Japan's production
capacity at home peaked in 1997. Constraints in
population growth force less production at home and more imports. The
share of imported manufactured products in the total Japanese imports
has risen from 50 percent in 1990 to 61 percent in 1999, rising by 11
percent. This increase in manufactured imports helped alleviate the
structural labor shrinkage.
The strategy of the
Japanese system of moving production overseas,
particularly to the rest of Asia, and importing the final products
seems to be a rational solution. The basic trade pattern of Japan
exporting capital, technology and essential parts to Asia, building
factories there, with the final products imported back to Japan or
re-exported to Europe and America, enables Japan to concentrate on the
high value added part of the production chain. The Asia shift of
Japan's trade is one of those Japanese efforts for tackling the
dwindling population while maintaining the same high level of income.
The size of the domestic market is related to the size of the
population. In the Japanese economy, personal consumption is about 60
percent of the domestic spending, by far the most important component
in Japan's economy, or for any country's economy. The peak of Japan's
population is forecast to come around 2007. It means that Japan's
domestic demand will still start to decrease after 2007, unless per
capita consumption starts increasing rapidly. The White Paper on the
Japanese Economy published by the Prime Minister's Office in November
2001 also concluded that the growth rate for Japan's economy for the
medium term is between 1 and 2 percent annually.
A country's economy
can have a sustainable source for financing needed
investment through state credits, rather than domestic saving, provided
there is adequate control on capital flow. With the world's largest
foreign-exchange reserve, Japan does not need to rely on domestic
savings for capital. In Japan, the wage earners' average annual saving
rate was 28.7 percent in 2000, inclusive of semi-annual bonus payments.
Such a high saving rate, a result of cultural behavior, has created a
high level of net financial asset for an average household of more than
14 million yen ($130,000) in September 2001, almost three times the
average Japanese annual income. The decrease of net household assets
from the year before was a mere 90,000 yen despite a collapse of the
equity market. This means the average Japanese has an income cushion of
almost three years even in these hard times. With this coupled with
social welfare provided by the public sector, the Japanese have a
strong safety net. No other country accumulates such high savings. Yet
the average household saving decreased only slightly even from rising
unemployment and reduced bonus payments from the recession.
Sustained by the
abundant supply of domestic saving, Japan's investment
has remained high even in the decade of low growth. Private-sector
investment is 16 percent of gross domestic expenditure (GDE), which is
the highest level among developed countries. Public investment is about
6 percent, housing is at 5 percent, making total investment 27 percent.
Japan's private-sector investment constitutes a high level of research
and development expenditure. In 2000, Japan's R&D expenditure was
3.2 percent of the GDP, again the highest level among the developed
countries. The United States spends 2.5 percent and the European Union
1.9 only percent.
Japan's high
saving/investment mechanism is also used in enhancing its
economic linkage with China. China has an abundant supply of
increasingly high-skilled, educated and young workforce, which is a
rapidly decreasing category in Japan. Japan in the 21st century, with
its rapidly aging and dwindling population, can establish a mutually
beneficial economic relation with China, even though wage levels
between the two economies may converge in time. Japan-China economic
relations are in a way an extension of Japan's economic relations with
Asia, but the nature and the degree of the ongoing changes in the
bilateral economic relations are very different from the rest of Asia.
Japanese export to
China in the first six months of 2002 grew 11
percent year to year to $17 billion and import fell 0.8 percent to $28
billion. Export to the rest of Asia fell 2.5 percent to $82 billion and
import fell 11.8 percent to $78 billion. Export to the United States
fell 9.9 percent to $57 billion and import fell 16.8 percent; and
export to the EU fell 17.2 percent to $29 billion and import fell 16.8
percent to $28 billion. Total export fell 7 percent to $195 billion and
import fell 14.2 percent to $157 billion.
China's export to
Japan rose in 2001 by 15 percent and imports by 11
percent, against a background of overall negative economic growth in
Japan. The biggest (29 percent) import item from China to Japan is
machinery, followed by textiles (27 percent).
The year 2001 was
the first time in history that machinery became
China's biggest export item. China is the only country in the world
that has succeeded in establishing a healthy trade surplus in machinery
products with Japan. This is the most significant change in the
Japan-China economic relations. At the same time, China remains
extremely competitive in the export of apparel, textile and shoes, the
traditional domain of exports for the developing countries. China's
competitiveness is not limited to manufacturing. Japan imported 750,000
tons of vegetables from China in 2001, a tenth of the price of domestic
production.
Lunchbox prices
have, as a result, fallen. Prices of Japanese
lunchboxes (obento) have fallen by 15
percent as a direct result. Some Japanese convenience stores have built
organic farms in China in order to use the vegetables into the lunchbox
sold in those stores in Japan. Vegetables and fish prices are falling
in Japan because of imports from China, benefiting consumers. But it
has dealt a blow to the numerous Japanese farmers' income. Clothing
prices have also fallen by 30-50 percent.
The deflationary
impact on the Japanese economy coming from China trade
will be long-lasting. From food and apparel to electronics, prices in
Japan will face falling pressures until the price levels of the two
countries reach some kind of equilibrium after many years. Thus Japan
has a vested interest in helping China to raise its wage levels. Slow
growth from a shrinking and aging population, shrinking export markets,
together with deflationary impact from China will depress the
profitability of Japanese corporations in the foreseeable future,
placing the Japanese economy in a long transition period of slow growth
and low profit margin. <> However, China
trade is expected to continue to benefit Japan. According to the World
Bank, Japan's benefit by China's entry into the World Trade
Organization (WTO) will be $61 billion by 2005, much larger than that
of North America, which is $38 billion. Hitachi plans to invest $1
billion in China by 2005. China's share in Hitachi's global production
of $40 billion will be 25 percent, the largest production share outside
Japan, four years from now. The highest-technology hardware and
software of Hitachi are to be manufactured and developed in China.
Hitachi has built a research lab for ubiquitous network technology
state-of-the-art technology in Beijing. Panasonic runs more than 40
companies for production in China. China will become the high-tech
consumer goods center of Asia, with Japanese companies playing an
important part in it.
With the rapid
merging of the two economies, tremendous changes are occurring. The new
competitiveness of China led Japan to impose protectionist measures
against three agricultural products: onions, rush (a plant used for
making tatami mats) and shiitake mushrooms from China in early June
2001, to which China retaliated by raising tariffs on selected Japanese
industrial products. After a seven-month impasse, the trade friction
was solved with a tacit orderly marketing agreement under the table, a
classical Asian solution that upset free traders. From shiitake
mushroom to the ubiquitous network software, the Japanese economy and
the Chinese economy are merging in an inexorable way. From the
lowest-tech to the highest-tech sector, the economies of the two
countries match and marry very well. The merger is creating a new
economic power in the world and will have significant impacts in world
economic history, with a revival of Asia as an economic and cultural
center, as it was in the 17th century.
Japan is already
the largest trading partner for China and the largest foreign direct
investment country in China, behind Taiwan and Hong Kong, which are
also Chinese. Although for Japan, the United States is by far the
largest trading partner because of Japan's big export to the US
historically and for now, the trend shows that China could surpass the
importance of the US and become the largest trading partner for Japan
in the near future. On the import side, it is already clear that by
this year, China will provide more goods to Japan than the United
States. The main obstacle for Japan-China economic cooperation is the
US-Japan political-military alliance.
China's restoration
of its political and military strength is a natural and inevitable
result of its long-overdue economic development. Instead of trying to
resist changes accompanied by the economic revival of China, the US-led
residual Cold War security framework needs to be reconsidered to
reflect new conditions in international security in East Asia. To
balance the growing economic ties between Japan and China, the economic
cooperation of the ASEAN (Association of Southeast Asian Nations) Plus
Three framework needs to be further pursued to promote peace and
prosperity in East Asia and the world.
Next: More on the Japanese
Experiennce
|
|
|
|
|