Super Capitalism, Super
Imperialism and Monetary Imperialism
By
Henry C.K. Liu
This article appeared in AToL
on October 12, 2007
Part I: A Structural Link
Robert B. Reich, former
US Secretary of Labor and resident neo-liberal in the Clinton
administration from
1993 to 1997 wrote in the September 14, 2007 edition of The Wall Street
Journal
an Opinion piece: CEOs Deserve Their Pay,
as part of an orchestrated campaign to promote his new book: Supercapitalism:
The Transformation of Business, Democracy, and Everyday Life (Afred A. Knopf).
Reich is a former Harvard professor
and the former Maurice
B. Hexter Professor of Social and Economic Policy at the Heller
School for
Social Policy and
Management at Brandeis University.
He is currently a professor at the Goldman School of Public Policy at
the University of California
(Berkley)
and a regular liberal gadfly in the unabashed supply-side Larry Kudlow
TV show
that celebrates the merits of capitalism.
Reich’s Supercapitalism
(2007) brings to mind Michael Hudson’s Super Imperialism: The
Economic
Strategy of American Empire (1972, 2003). While Reich, a liberal
turned neo-liberal,
sees “supercapitalism” as the natural
evolution of insatiable shareholder appetite for gain, a polite
euphemism for greed
that cannot or should not be reined in by regulation, Hudson,
a Marxist heterodox economist, sees “super
imperialism” as the structural outcome of post-WWII superpower
geopolitics
with state interests overwhelming free market forces, making regulation
irrelevant. While Hudson is critical of “super
imperialism” and thinks that it should be resisted by the weaker
trading
partners of the US, Reich gives the impression of being ambivalent
about the
inevitability if not the benignity of “supercapitalsim”.
The structural link between
capitalism and imperialism was
first observed by John Atkinson Hobson (1858-1940), English economist,
who
wrote in 1902 an insightful analysis of the economic basis of
imperialism.
Hobson provided a humanist critique of neoclassical economics,
rejecting
exclusively materialistic definitions of value. With Albert
Frederick Mummery (1855-1895), the great British
Mountaineer who was tragically killed in 1895 by an avalanche whilst
reconnoitering the Rakhiot Face of Nanga Parbat, an 8,000-meter
Himalayan peak,
Hobson wrote The Physiology of Industry (1889), which argued
that an
industrial economy requires government intervention to maintain
stability, and developed
the theory of over-saving that was given an overflowing tribute by John
Maynard
Keynes three decades later.
The need for governmental
intervention to stabilize an
expanding national industrial economy was the rationale for political
imperialism. On the other side of the coin, protectionism was a
governmental
counter-intervention on the part of weak trading partners for resisting
imperialist expansion of the dominant power. Historically,
the processes of globalization have always been the result of active
state policy
and action, as opposed to the mere passive surrender of state
sovereignty to
market forces. Market forces cannot operate in a vacuum. They are
governed by
man-made rules. Globalized markets require the acceptance by local
authorities
of established rules of the dominant economy. Currency monopoly of
course is
the most fundamental trade restraint by one single dominant government.
Adam Smith published Wealth
of Nations in 1776, the year of US
independence. By the time the constitution was
framed 11 years later, the US
founding fathers were deeply influenced by Smith’s ideas, which
constituted a reasoned
abhorrence of trade monopoly and government policy in restricting
trade. What
Smith abhorred most was a policy known as mercantilism, which was
practiced by
all the major powers of the time. It is necessary to bear in mind that
Smith’s
notion of the limitation of government action was exclusively related
to
mercantilist issues of trade restraint. Smith never advocated
government
tolerance of trade restraint, whether by big business monopolies or by
other
governments in the name of open markets.
A central aim of mercantilism was to
ensure that a nation’s exports remained
higher in value than its imports, the surplus in that era being paid
only in
specie money (gold-backed as opposed to fiat money). This trade surplus
in gold
permitted the surplus country, such as England,
to invest in more factories at home to manufacture
more for export, thus bringing home more gold. The importing regions,
such as
the American colonies, not only found the gold reserves backing their
currency
depleted, causing free-fall devaluation (not unlike that faced today by
many
emerging-economy currencies), but also wanting in surplus capital for
building
factories to produce for domestic consumption and export. So despite
plentiful
iron ore in America,
only pig iron was exported to England
in return for English finished iron goods. The
situation was similar to today’s oil producing countries where despite
plentiful crude oil, refined petrochemical products such as gasoline
and
heating oil had to be imported.
In 1795, when the newly independent
Americans began finally to wake up to their disadvantaged
trade relationship and began to raise European (mostly French and
Dutch)
capital to start a manufacturing industry, England decreed the Iron
Act,
forbidding the manufacture of iron goods in its American colonies,
which caused
great dissatisfaction among the prospering colonials. Smith favored an
opposite
government policy toward promoting domestic economic production and
free
foreign trade for the weaker traders, a policy that came to be known as
"laissez faire" (because the English,
having nothing to do with such heretical ideas, refuse to give it an
English
name). Laissez faire, notwithstanding
its literal meaning of “leave alone”, meant nothing of the sort. It
meant an
activist government policy to counteract mercantilism. Neo-liberal
free-market
economists are just bad historians, among their other defective
characteristics, when they propagandize “laissez
faire” as no government interference in trade affairs.
Friedrich List, in his National
System of Political
Economy (1841), asserts that political economy as espoused in England,
far from being a valid science universally, was merely British national
opinion, suited only to English historical conditions.
List’s institutional school of economics
asserts that the doctrine of free trade was devised to keep England
rich and powerful at the expense of its trading partners and it must be
fought
with protective tariffs and other protective devises of economic
nationalism by
the weaker countries. Henry Clay’s “American system” was a national
system of
political economy. US
neo-imperialism in the post WWII period disingenuously promotes
neo-liberal free-trade
against governmental protectionism to keep the US
rich and powerful at the expense of its trading partners. Before the
October Revolution
of 1917, many national liberation movements in European colonies and
semi-colonies
around the world were influenced by List’s economic nationalism. The
1911 Nationalist Revolution led by Dr. Sun Yat-sen was heavily
influenced by Lincoln's political ideas government of the people, by
the people and for the people, and the economic nationalism of List
until after the October Revolution when Dr. Sun realized that the
Soviet model was the correct path to national revival.
Hobson’s magnum opus, Imperialism
(1902),
argues that imperialistic expansion is driven not by state hubris,
known in US history as Manifest Destiny, but by an innate quest for new
markets and
investment opportunities overseas for excess capital formed by
over-saving at
home for the benefit of the home state. Over-saving
during the industrial age came
from Richardo’s theory of the iron law of wages according to which
wages were
kept perpetually at subsistence levels as a result of uneven market
power
between capital and labor. Today, job outsourcing that returns as
low-price
imports contributes to the iron law of wages in the US
domestic economy. See my AToL article: Organization of
Labor Exporting Countries
(OLEC).
Hobson’s analysis of the phenology
(life cycles study) of
capitalism was drawn upon by Lenin to formulate a theory of imperialism
as an
advanced stage of capitalism: “Imperialism is capitalism at that stage
of
development at which the dominance of monopolies and finance capitalism
is
established; in which the export of capital has acquired pronounced
importance;
in which the division of the world among the international trusts has
begun, in
which the division of all territories of the globe among the biggest
capitalist
powers has been completed.” (Vladimir Ilyich Lenin, 1870-1924, Imperialism,
the Highest Stage of Capitalism, Chapter 7 - 1916).
Lenin was also influenced by Rosa
Luxemberg, who three year
earlier had written her major work: The
Accumulation of Capital: A Contribution to an Economic Explanation of
Imperialism (Die Akkumulation des
Kapitals: Ein Beitrag zur ökonomischen Erklärung
des Imperialismus, 1913). Luxemberg, together with Karl
Liebknecht,
founding leaders of the Spartacist
League (Spartakusbund), a
radical Marxist revolutionary movement that later renamed itself the
Communist
Party of Germany (Kommunistische Partei Deutschlands, or KPD),
was
murdered on January 15, 1919 by members of the Freikorps,
rightwing militarists who were the forerunners of the
Nazi Sturmabteilung (SA) led by Ernst
Röhm.
The congenital association between
capitalism and
imperialism requires practically all truly anti-imperialist movements
the world
over to be also anti-capitalist. To this day, most nationalist
capitalists in
emerging economies are unwitting neo-compradors for super imperialism.
Neo-liberalism,
in its attempts to breakdown all national boundaries to facilitate
global trade
denominated in fiat dollars, is the ideology of super imperialism.
Hudson, American heterodox economist,
historian of ancient
economies and post-World War II international balance-of-payments
specialist, advanced
in his 1972 book the notion of 20th-century super
imperialism. Hudson
updated Hobson’s idea of 19th-century imperialism of state
industrial
policy seeking new markets to invest home-grown excess capital. To Hudson,
super imperialism is a state financial strategy to export debt
denominated in the
state’s fiat currency as capital to the new financial colonies to
finance the global
expansion of a superpower empire. No necessity, or even intention, was
entertained by the superpower of ever having to pay off these paper
debts after
the US dollar was taken off gold in 1971.
Monetary
Imperialism
and Dollar Hegemony
Super imperialism transformed into
monetary imperialism
after the 1973 Middle East oil crisis with the
creation
of the petrodollar and two decades later emerged as dollar hegemony
through
financial globalization after 1993. As described in my 2002 AToL
article: Dollar Hegemony has to go, a
geopolitical phenomenon emerged after the 1973 oil crisis in which the
US
dollar, a fiat currency since 1971, continues to serve as the primary
reserve
currency for international trade because oil continues to be
denominated in fiat
dollars as a result of superpower geopolitics, leading to dollar
hegemony in
1993 with the globalization of deregulated financial markets.
Three causal developments allowed
dollar hegemony to emerge
over a span of two decades since 1973 that finally took hold in 1993. US
fiscal deficits from overseas spending since the 1950s caused a massive
drain
in US gold holdings to force the US
in 1971 to abandon the 1945 Bretton Woods regime of fixed exchange rate
based
on a gold-backed dollar. Under that international financial
architecture, cross-border
flow of funds was not considered necessary or desirable for promoting
international
trade or domestic development. The collapse of the 1945 Bretton Woods
regime in
1971 was the initial development toward dollar hegemony.
The second development was the
denomination of oil in
dollars after the 1973 Middle East oil crisis.
The
emergence of petrodollars was the price the US,
still only one of two contending superpowers in 1973, extracted from
defenseless
oil-producing nations for allowing them to nationalize the
Western-owned oil
industry on their soil. As long as oil transactions are denominated in
fiat
dollars, the US
essentially controls all the oil in the world financially regardless of
specific
ownership, reducing all oil producing nations to the status of
commodity agents
of dollar hegemony.
The third development was the global
deregulation of financial
markets after the Cold War, making cross-border flow of funds routine
and a
general relaxation of capital and foreign exchange control by most
governments
involved in international trade. This
neo-liberal trade regime brought into existence a foreign exchange
market in
which free-floating exchange rates made computerized speculative
attacks on weak
currencies a regular occurrence. These three developments permitted the
emergence of dollar hegemony after 1994 and helped the US
win the Cold War with financial power derived from fiat money.
Dollar hegemony advanced super
imperialism one stage further
from the financial to the monetary front. Industrial imperialism sought
to achieve
a trade surplus by exporting manufactured good to the colonies for gold
to fund
investment for more productive plants at home. Super imperialism sought
to extract
real wealth from the colonies by paying for it with fiat dollars to
sustain a
balance of payments out of an imbalance in the exchange of commodities.
Monetary imperialism under dollar hegemony exports debt denominated in
fiat
dollars through a permissive trade deficit with the new colonies, only
to re-import
the debt back to the US
as capital account surplus to finance the US
debt bubble.
The circular recycling of
dollar-denominated debt was made operative
by the dollar, a fiat currency that only the US
can print at will, continuing as the world’s prime reserve currency for
international
trade and finance, backed by US
geopolitical superpower. Dollars are accepted universally because oil
is
denominated in dollars and everyone needs oil and thus needs dollar to
buy oil.
Any nation that seeks to denominate key commodities, such as oil, in
currencies
other than the dollar will soon find itself invaded by the sole
superpower.
Thus the war on Iraq
is not about oil, as former Federal Reserve Chairman Alan Greenspan
suggests
recently. It is about keeping oil denominated in dollars to protect
dollar
hegemony. The difference is subtle but of essential importance.
Since 1993, central banks of all
trading nations around the
world, with the exception of the US Federal Reserve, have been forced
to hold
more dollar reserves than they otherwise need to ward off the potential
of sudden
speculative attacks on their currencies in unregulated global financial
markets. Thus “dollar hegemony” prevents the exporting nations, such as
the
Asian Tigers, from spending domestically the dollars they earn from the
US
trade deficit and forces them to fund the US
capital account surplus, shipping real wealth to the US
in exchange for the privilege of financing further growth of the US
debt economy.
Not only do these exporting nations
have to compete by keeping
their domestic wages down and by prostituting their environment, the
dollars
that they earn cannot be spent at home without causing a monetary
crisis in
their own currencies because the dollars they earn have to be exchanged
into local
currencies before they can be spent domestically, causing an excessive
rise in
their domestic money supply which in turn causes domestic
inflation-pushed
bubbles. Meanwhile, while the trade-surplus nations are forces to lend
their
export earnings back to the US,
these same nations are starve for capital as global capital denominated
in
dollars will only invest in their export sectors to earn more dollars.
The domestic
sector with local currency earnings remain of little interest to global
capital
denominated in dollars. As a result, domestic development stagnates for
lack of
capital.
Dollar hegemony permits the US
to transform itself from a competitor in world markets to earn hard
money, to a
fiat-money-making monopoly with fiat dollars that only it can print at
will.
Every other trading nation has to exchange low-wage goods for dollars
that the US
alone can
print freely and that can be spend only in the dollar economy without
monetary
penalty.
The Victimization of Japan and China
Japan
is a classic case of a victim of monetary imperialism. In 1990, as a
result of
Japanese export prowess, the Industrial Bank of Japan
was the largest bank in the world, with a market capitalization of $57
billion.
The top nine of the 10 largest banks then were all Japanese, trailed by
Canadian
Alliance in 10th place. No US
bank made the top-ten list. By 2001, the effects of dollar hegemony
have pushed
Citigroup into first place with a market capitalization of $260
billion. Seven
of the top ten largest financial institutions in the world in 2001 were
US-based,
with descending ranking in market capitalization: Citigroup ($260
billion), AIG
($209 billion), HSBC (British-$110 billion), Berkshire Hathaway ($100
billion),
Bank of America ($99 billion), Fanny Mae ($80 billion), Wells Fargo
($74
billion), JP Morgan Chase ($72 billion), RBS (British-$70 billion) and
UBS
(Swiss-$67 billion). No Japanese bank survived on the list.
China
is a neoclassic case of dollar hegemony victimization even though its
domestic
financial markets are still not open and the RMB yuan is still not
freely
convertible. With over $1.4 trillion in foreign exchange reserves
earned at a previously
lower fixed exchange rate of 8.2 to a dollar set in 1985, now growing
at the
rate of $1 billion a day at a narrow range floating exchange rate of
around 7.5
since July 2005, China cannot spend much of its dollar holdings on
domestic
development without domestic inflation caused by excessive expansion of
its
yuan money supply. The Chinese economy is overheating because the bulk
of its surplus
revenue is in dollars from exports that cannot be spent inside China
without monetary penalty. Chinese wages are too low to absorb sudden
expansion
of yuan money supply to develop the domestic economy. And with over
$1.4
trillion in foreign exchange reserves, equal to its annual GDP, China
cannot even divest from the dollar without having the market effect of
a
falling dollar moving against its remaining holdings.
The People's Bank of China announced
on July 20, 2005
that effective immediately the yuan
exchange rate would go up by 2.1% to 8.11 yuan to the US dollar and
that China
would drop the dollar peg to its currency. In its place, China
would move to a “managed float” of the yuan, pegging the currency’s
exchange
value to an undisclosed basket of currencies linked to its global
trade. In an
effort to limit the amount of volatility, China
would not allow the currency to fluctuate by more than 0.3% in any one
trading
day. Linking the yuan to a basket of currencies means China's
currency is relatively free from market forces acting on the dollar,
shifting
to market forces acting on a basket of currencies of China’s
key trading partners. The basket is composed of the euro, yen and other
Asian
currencies as well as the dollar. Though the precise composition of the
basket
was not disclosed, it can nevertheless be deduced by China’s
trade volume with key trading partners and by mathematic calculation
from the
set-daily exchange rate.
Thus China
is trapped into a trade regime operating on an international monetary
architecture in which it must continue to export real wealth in the
form of
underpaid labor and polluted environment in exchange for dollars that
it must
reinvest in the US.
Ironically, the recent rise of anti-trade sentiment in US domestic
politics
offers China
a convenient,
opportune escape from dollar hegemony to reduce its dependence on
export to
concentrate on domestic development. Chinese domestic special interest
groups
in the export sector would otherwise oppose any policy to slow the
growth in
export if not for the rise of US protectionism which causes shot-term
pain for
China but long-term benefit in China’s need to restructure its economy
toward
domestic development. Further trade surplus denominated in dollar is of
no
advantage to China.
Emerging
Markets Are
New Colonies of Monetary Imperialism
Even as the domestic US
economy declines since the onset of globalization in the early 1990s, US
dominance in global finance has continued to this day on account of
dollar
hegemony. It should not be surprising that the nation that can print at
will
the world’s reserve currency for international trade should come up on
top in
deregulated global financial markets. The so-called emerging markets
around the
world are the new colonies of monetary imperialism in a global
neo-liberal
trading regime operating under dollar hegemony geopolitically dominated
by the US
as the world’s sole remaining superpower.
Denial
of Corporate
Social Responsibility
In Supercapitalism,
Reich identifies corporate social responsibility as a diversion from
economic
efficiency and an un-capitalistic illusion. Of course the late Milton
Friedman had
asserted that the only social responsibility corporations have is to
maximize
profit, rather than to generate economic well-being and balanced growth
through
fair profits. There is ample evidence to suggest that single purpose
quest for
maximizing global corporate profit can lead to domestic economic
decline in
even the world’s sole remaining superpower. The US public is encouraged
to
blame such decline on the misbehaving trading partners of the US rather
than US
trade policy that permits US transnational corporation to exploit
workers in
all trading nations, including those in the US. It is a policy that
devalues
work by over-rewarding financial manipulation.
Yet to Reich, the US
corporate income tax is regressive and inequitable and should be
abolished so
that after-tax corporate profit can be even further enhanced. This
pro-profit
position is at odds with even rising Republican sentiments against
transnational corporations and their global trade strategies. Reich
also thinks
the concept of corporate criminal liability is based on an
“anthropomorphic
fallacy” that ends up hurting innocent people. Reich sees as inevitable
an
evolutionary path towards an allegedly perfect new world of a super
energetic
capitalism responding to the dictate of all-powerful consumer
preference
through market democracy.
Reich argues that corporations cannot
be expected to be more
“socially responsible” than their shareholders or even their consumers,
and he
implies that consumer preference and behavior are the proper and
effective police
forces that supersede the need for market regulation. He sees
corporations, while
viewed by law as “legal persons”, as merely value-neutral institutional
respondents of consumer preferences in global markets. Reich claims
that corporate
policies, strategies and behavior in market capitalism are effectively
governed
by consumer preferences and need no regulation by government. This is
essentially the ideology of neo-liberalism.
Yet US transnational corporations
derive profit from global
operations serving global consumers to maximize return on global
capital. These
transnational corporations will seek to shift production to where labor
is
cheapest and environmental standards are lowest and to market their
products
where prices are highest and consumer purchasing power the strongest.
Often,
these corporations find it more profitable to sell products they
themselves do
not make, controlling only design and marketing, leaving the dirty side
of
manufacturing to others with underdeveloped market power. This means if
the US
wants a trade surplus under the current terms of trade, it must lower
its wages.
The decoupling of consumers from producers weakens the conventional
effects of
market pressure on corporate social responsibility. Transnational
corporations
have no home community loyalty. Consumers generally do not care about
sweat
shop conditions overseas while overseas workers do not care about
product
safety on goods they produce but cannot afford to buy. Products may be
made in China,
but they are not made by China,
but by US transnational corporations which are responsible for the
quality and
safety of their products.
Further, it is well recognized that
corporations routinely
and effectively manipulate consumer preference and market acceptance
often through
if not false, at least misleading advertising, not for the benefit of
consumers, but to maximize return on faceless capital raised from
global
capital markets. The subliminal emphasis by the
corporate
culture on addictive acquisition of material things, coupled with a
structural deprivation
of adequate income to satisfy the manipulated desires, has made
consumers less satisfied
than in previous times of less material abundance. Corporations have
been
allowed to imbed consumption-urging messages into every aspect of
modern life.
The result is a disposable culture with packaged waste, an obesity
crisis for
all age groups, skyrocketing consumer debt, the privatization of public
utility
that demand the same fee for basic services from rich and poor alike,
causing
sharp disparity in affordability. It is a phenomenon described
by Karl Marx
as a “fetish of commodities”.
Marx’s Concept of
Fetish of Commodities
Marx wrote in Das
Kapital, Volume One, Part I: Commodities
and Money, Chapter One: Commodities, Section I:
“The relation of the producers to the sum
total of their own labor is presented to them as a social relation,
existing
not between themselves, but between the products of their labor. This
is the
reason why the products of labor become commodities, social things
whose qualities
are at the same time perceptible and imperceptible by the senses. … …
The
existence of the things quâ commodities, and the value
relation between
the products of labor which stamps them as commodities, have absolutely
no
connection with their physical properties and with the material
relations
arising there from. It is a definite social relation between men that
assumes,
in their eyes, the fantastic form of a relation between things. In
order,
therefore, to find an analogy, we must have recourse to the
mist-enveloped
regions of the religious world. In that world, the productions of the
human
brain appear as independent beings endowed with life, and entering into
relation both with one another and the human race. So it is in the
world of
commodities with the products of men’s hands. This I call the Fetishism which attaches itself to the
products of labor, as soon as they are produced as commodities, and
which is
therefore inseparable from the production of commodities.
This Fetishism of Commodities has its
origin … in the peculiar social character of
the labor that produces them.”
Marx asserts that “the mystical
character of commodities
does not originate in their use-value” (Section 1, p. 71).
Market value is derived from social
relations, not from use-value which is a material phenomenon. Thus Marx
critiques
the Marginal Utility Theory by pointing out that market value is
affected by
social relationships. For example, the marginal utility of door locks
is a
function of the burglary rate in a neighborhood which in turn is a
function of
the unemployment rate. Unregulated free markets are a regime of
uninhibited
price gouging by monopolies and cartels.
Thus the nature of money cannot be
adequately explained even
in terms of the material-technical properties of gold, but only in
terms of the
factors behind man’s desire and need for gold. Similarly, it is not
possible to
fully understand the price of capital from the technical nature of the
means of
production, but only from the social institution of private ownership
and the
terms of exchange imposed by uneven market power. Market
capitalism is a social institution
based on the fetishism of commodities.
Democracy
Threatened
by the Corporate State
While Reich is on target in warning
about the danger to democracy
posed by the corporate state, and in claiming that only people can be
citizens,
and only citizens should participate in democratic decision making, he
misses
the point that transnational corporations have transcended national
boundaries.
Yet in each community these transnational corporations operate, they
have the congenital
incentive, the financial means and the legal mandate to manipulate the
fetishism of commodities even in distant lands.
More over, representative democracy
as practiced in the US
is increasingly manipulated by corporate lobbying funded from
high-profit-driven corporate financial resources derived from foreign
sources controlled
by management. Corporate governance is notoriously abusive of minority
shareholder
rights on the part of management. Notwithstanding Reich’s
rationalization of
excessive CEO compensation, CEOs as a class is the most vocal proponent
of corporate
statehood. Modern corporations are securely insulated from any serious
threats
from consumer revolt. Inter-corporate competition presents only
superficial and
trivial choices for consumers. Motorists have never been offered any
real
choice on gasoline by oil companies or alternatives on the
gasoline-guzzling
internal combustion engine by car-makers.
High
Pay for CEOs
Reich asserts in his WSJ Opinion
piece that modern CEOs in
finance capitalism nowadays deserve their high pay because they have to
be
superstars, unlike their bureaucrat-like predecessors during industrial
capitalism. Notwithstanding that one
would expect a former Labor Secretary to argue that workers deserve
higher pay,
the challenge to corporate leadership in market capitalism has always
been and
will always remain management’s ruthless pursuit of market leadership
power, a
euphemism for monopoly, by skirting the rule of law and regulations,
framing legislative
regimes through political lobbying, pushing down wages and worker
benefits, increasing
productivity by downsizing in an expanding market and manipulating
consumer
attitude through advertising. At the end of the day, the bottom line
for
corporate profit is a factor of lowering wage and benefit levels.
Reich seems to have forgotten that
the captains of industry of
the 19th century of free-wheeling capitalism were all
superstars who
evoked public admiration by manipulating the awed public into accepting
the
Horatio Alger myth of success through hard work, honesty and fairness.
The
derogatory term “robber barons” was first coined by protest pamphlets
circulated by victimized Kansas
farmers against ruthless railroad tycoons during the Great Depression.
The
manipulation of the public will by the moneyed interests is the most
problematic vulnerability of US
economic and political democracy. In an era when class warfare has
taken on new
sophistication, the accusation of resorting to class warfare arguments
is
widely used to silent legitimate socio-economic protests. The US
media is essentially owned by the moneyed interests. The decline of
unionism in
the US
has been
largely the result of anti-labor propaganda campaigns funded by
corporations and
government policies influenced by corporate lobbyists.
Inflitration of organized crime was exploited
to fan public antiunion sentiments while widespread corporate white
collar
crimes were dismissed as mere anomalies. See my AToL article : Capitalism’s bad apples:
It’s the
barrel that's rotten
Superman
Capitalism
As promoted by his permissive WSJ
Opinion piece, a more apt
title for Professor Reich’s new book would be: Superman
Capitalism, in praise of the super-heroic qualities of successful
corporate chief executive officers who deserve superstar pay. This view goes beyond even fascist superman
ideology.
The compensation of corporate CEOs in NAZI Germany never reached such
obscene
levels as those in US
corporate land today.
Reich argues that CEOs deserve their
super-high compensation,
which has increased 600% in two decades, because corporate profits have
also
risen 600% in the same period. The
former Secretary of Labor did not point out that wages rose only 30% in
the
same period. The profit/wage disparity is a growing cancer in the
US-dominated
global economy, causing over-production resulting from stagnant demand
caused
by inadequate wages. A true spokesman
for labor would point out that enlightened modern management recognizes
that
the performance of a corporation is the sum total of effective team
work between
management and labor.
System analysis has long shown that
collective effort on the
part of the entire work force is indispensable to success in any
complex
organism. Further, a healthy consumer market depends on a balance
between
corporate earnings and worker earnings. Reich’s point would be valid if
US
wages had risen on the same multiple as CEO pay and corporate profit,
but he
apparently thought that it would be poor etiquette to raise
embarrassing issues
as a guest writer in an innately anti-labor journal of Wall Street.
Even then,
unless real growth also rose 600% in two decades, the rise in corporate
earning
may be just an inflation bubble.
An
Introduction to
Economic Populism
To be fair, Reich did address the
income gap issue eight
months earlier in another article: An
Introduction to Economic Populism in the Jan-Feb, 2007 issue of The American Prospect, a magazine that
bills itself as devoted to “liberal ideas”. In
that article, Reich relates a
“philosophical” discussion he had with fellow
neo-liberal cabinet member Robert Rubin, then Treasury Secretary under Clinton,
on two “simple questions”.
The first question was: Suppose a
proposed policy will
increase the incomes of some people without decreasing the incomes of
any
others. Of course Reich must know that it is a question of welfare
economics
long ago answered by the Pareto Optimum, which asserts that resources
are
optimally distributed when an individual cannot move into a better
position
without putting someone else into a worse position. In an unjust
society, the Pareto
Optimum will perpetuate injustice in the name of optimum resource
allocation. “Should
it be implemented? Bob and I agreed it should,” writes Reich. Not
exactly an
earth-shaking liberal position. Rather, it is a classic neo-liberal
posture.
And the second question: But suppose
the people whose
incomes will rise are already wealthier than everyone else. Although no
one
will lose ground, inequality will widen. Should it still be
implemented? “I
won’t tell you where he and I came out on that second question,” writes
Reich
without explaining why. He allows that “we agreed that people who don’t
share
in such gains feel relatively poorer. Widening inequality also further
tips the
balance of political power in favor of the wealthy.”
Of course, clear thinking would have
left the second
question mute because it would have invalidated the first question
since the
real income of those whose nominal income has not fallen has indeed
fallen relative
to those whose nominal income has risen. In a macro monetary sense, it
is not
possible to raise the nominal income of some without lower the real
income of
others. All incomes must rise together proportionally or inequality in
after-inflation real income will increase.
Inequality
only a New
Worry?
But for the sake of argument, let’s
go along with Reich’s
parable on welfare economics and financial equality. That conversation
between
the Secretary of Labor and the Treasury Secretary occurred a decade
ago. Reich
says in his January 2007 WSJ Opinion piece that “inequality is far more
worrisome now”, as if it had not been or that the policies he and his
colleagues
in the Clinton administration, as evidenced by their answer to their
own first
question, did not caused the now “more worrisome” inequality. “The
incomes of
the bottom 90% of Americans have increased about 2% in real terms since
then,
while that of the top 1% has increased over 50%,” Reich wrote in a
matter of
fact tone of an innocent bystander.
It is surprising that a
former Labor Secretary would err even
on the record on worker income. The Internal Revenue Service reports
that while
incomes have been rising since 2002, the average income in 2005 was
$55,238,
nearly 1% less than in 2000 after adjusting for inflation. Hourly wage costs (including mandatory welfare
contributions and
benefits) grew more slowly than hourly
productivity from 1993 to late
1997, the years
of Reich’s tenure as Labor Secretary. Corporate profit rose until 1997
before
declining, meaning what should have gone to workers from productivity
improvements went instead to corporate profits. And corporate profit
declined
after 1997 because of the Asian Financial crisis which reduced offshore
income
for all transnational companies while domestic purchasing power
remained weak
because of sub-par worker income growth.
The break in trends in wages occurred when the
unemployment
rate sank to 5%, below the 6% threshold of NAIRU (non-accelerating
inflation rate of unemployment) as job
creation was
robust from 1993 onwards. The “reserve army of labor” in the war
against
inflation disappeared after the 1997 Asian financial crisis when the
Federal
Reserve injected liquidity into the US banking system to launch the debt bubble.
According to
NAIRU, when more than 94% of the labor force is employed, the war on
wage-pushed
inflation will be on the defensive. Yet while US inflation was held down by low-price imports
from low-wage
economies, US domestic wages fell behind productivity growth from 1993
onward. US wage
could have risen without inflationary effects but did
not because of the threat of further outsourcing of US jobs overseas.
This caused
corporate profit to rise at the expense of labor income during the
low-inflation
debt bubble years.
Income inequality in the US
today has reached extremes not seen since the 1920s, but the trend
started
three decades earlier. More than $1 trillion a year in relative income
is now
being shifted annually from roughly 90,000,000 middle and working class
families to the wealthiest households and corporations via corporate
profits
earned from low-wage workers overseas. This is why nearly 60% of
Republicans
polled support more taxes on the rich.
Carter
the Grand
Daddy of Deregulation
The policies and practices
responsible for today’s widening
income gap date back to the 1977-1981 period of the Carter
administration which
is justly known as the administration of deregulation. Carter’s
deregulation
was done in the name of populism but the results were largely
anti-populist. Starting
with Carter, policies and practices by both corporations and government
underwent
a fundamental shift to restructure the US
economy with an overhaul of job markets. This was achieved through
widespread
de-unionization, breakup of industry-wide collective bargaining which
enabled
management to exploit a new international division of labor at the
expense of
domestic workers.
The frontal assault on worker
collective bargaining power
was accompanied by a realigning of the progressive federal tax
structure to cut
taxes on the rich, a brutal neo-liberal global free-trade offensive by
transnational
corporations and anti-labor government trade policies. The cost
shifting of
health care and pension plans from corporations to workers was condoned
by
government policy. A wave of government-assisted compression of wages
and
overtime pay narrowed the wage gap between the lowest and highest paid
workers
(which will occur when lower-paid workers receive a relatively larger
wage
increase than the higher-paid workers with all workers receiving lower
pay
increases than managers). There was a recurring diversion of
inflation-driven social
security fund surpluses to the US
fiscal budget to offset recurring inflation-adjusted federal deficits. This was accompanied by wholesale anti-trust
deregulation
and privatization of public sectors; and most egregious of all,
financial
market deregulation.
Carter deregulated the US
oil industry four years after the 1973 oil crisis in the name of
national
security. His Democratic challenger, Senator Ted Kennedy, advocated
outright
nationalization. The Carter administration also deregulated the
airlines, favoring
profitable hub traffic at the expense of traffic to smaller cities. Air fare fell but service fell further.
Delays became routine, frequently tripling door-to-door travel time.
What
consumers save in airfare, they pay dearly in time lost in delay and in
in-flight
discomfort. The Carter administration also deregulated trucking which
caused
the Teamsters Union to support Reagan in exchange for a promise to
delay
trucking deregulation.
Railroads were also deregulated by
Railroad Revitalization
and Regulatory Reform Act of 1976 which eased regulations on rates,
line
abandonment, and mergers to allow the industry to compete with truck
and barge
transportation that had caused a financial and physical deterioration
of the
national rail network railroads. Four
years later, Congress followed up with
the Staggers Rail Act of
1980 which provided the railroads with greater pricing freedom,
streamlined
merger timetables, expedited the line abandonment process, and allowed
confidential contracts with shippers. Although railroads, like other
modes of
transportation, must purchase and maintain their own rolling stock and
locomotives, they must also, unlike competing modes, construct and
maintain
their own roadbed, tracks, terminals, and related facilities. Highway
construction and maintenance are paid for by gasoline taxes. In the
regulated
environment, recovering these fixed costs hindered profitability for
the rail industry.
After deregulation, the railroads
sought to enhance their
financial situation and improve their operational efficiency with a mix
of
strategies of reducing cost to maximize profit rather than providing
needed
service to passengers around the nation. These strategies included
network
rationalization by shedding unprofitable capacity, raising equipment
and
operational efficiencies by new work rules that reduce safety margins
and union
power, using differential pricing to favor big shippers, and pursuing
consolidation,
reducing the number of rail companies from 65 to 5 today. The
consequence was a
significant increase of market power for the merged rail companies,
decreasing transportation
options for consumers and increasing rates for remote, less dense areas.
In the agricultural sector, rail
network rationalization has
forced shippers to truck their bulk commodity products greater
distances to
mainline elevators, resulting in greater pressure on and damage to
rural road
systems. For inter-modal shippers, profit-based network rationalization
has
meant reduced access—physically and economically—to Container on Flat
Car
(COFC) and Trailer on Flat Car (TOFC) facilities and services. Rail
deregulation, as is true with most transportation and communication
deregulation, produces sector sub-optimization with dubious benefits
for the
national economy by distorting distributional balance, causing
congestion and
inefficient use of land, network and lines.
Carter’s
Federal Communications Commission's (FCC) approach
to radio and television regulation began in the mid-1970s as a search
for
relatively minor “regulatory underbrush” that could be cleared away for
more
efficient and cost-effective administration of the important rules that
would
remain. Congress largely went along with this updating trend, and
initiated a
few deregulatory moves of its own to make regulation more effective and
responsive to contemporary conditions.
Reagan’s
Anti-Government Fixation
The Reagan Administration under FCC
Chairman Mark Fowler in
1981 shifted deregulation to a fundamental and ideologically-driven
reappraisal
of regulations away from long-held principles central to national
broadcasting
policy appropriate for a democratic society. The result was removal of
many
longstanding rules to permit an overall reduction in FCC oversight of
station ownership
concentration and network operations. Congress grew increasingly wary
of the
pace of deregulation, however, and began to slow the pace of FCC
deregulation
by the late 1980s.
Specific deregulatory moves included
(a) extending
television licenses to five years from three in 1981; (b) expanding the
number
of television stations any single entity could own grew from seven in
1981 to
12 in 1985 with further changes in 1995; (c) abolishing guidelines for
minimal
amounts of non-entertainment programming in 1985; (d) elimination of
the Fairness
Doctrine in 1987; (e) dropping, in 1985, FCC license guidelines for how
much
advertising could be carried; (f) leaving technical standards
increasingly in
the hands of licensees rather than FCC mandates; and (g) deregulation
of
television's competition especially cable which went through several
regulatory
changes in the decade after 1983.
The 1996 Telecommunications Act
eliminated the 40-station
ownership cap on radio stations. Since then, the radio industry
has
experienced unprecedented consolidation. In June 2003, the FCC
voted to
overhaul limits on media ownership. Despite having held only one
hearing
on the complex issue of media consolidation over a 20-month review
period, the
FCC, in a party-line vote, voted 3-2 to overhaul limits on media
concentration.
The rule would (1) increase the aggregate television ownership cap to
enable
one company to own stations reaching 45% of our nation's
homes (from 35%),
(2) lift the ban on newspaper-television cross-ownership, and (3) allow
a
single company to own three television stations in large media markets
and two
in medium ones. In the largest markets, the rule would allow a
single
company to own up to three television stations, eight radio stations,
the cable
television system, cable television stations, and a daily
newspaper. A
wide range of public-interest groups filed an appeal with the Third
Circuit,
which stayed the effective date of the new rules.
According to a BIA
Financial Network report released in July
2006, a total of 88 television stations had been sold in the first six
months
of 2006, generating a transaction value of $15.7 billion. In 2005, the
same
period saw the sale of just 21 stations at a value of $244 million,
with total
year transactions of $2.86 billion.
Congress passed a law in 2004 that
forbids any network to
own a group of stations that reaches more than 39% of the national
television
audience. That is lower than the 45% limit set in 2003, but more than
the
original cap of 35% set in 1996 under the Clinton administration —
leading
public interest groups to argue that the proposed limits lead to a
stifling of
local voices.
Newspaper-television cross-ownership
remains a contentious
issue. Currently prohibited, it refers to the “common ownership of a
full-service broadcast station and a daily newspaper when the broadcast
station’s area of coverage (or ‘contour’ as it is known in the
industry)
encompasses the newspaper’s city of publication.” Capping of local
radio and
television ownership is another issue. While the original rule
prohibited it,
currently a company can own at least one television and one radio
station in a
market. In larger markets, “a single entity may own additional radio
stations
depending on the number of other independently owned media outlets in
the
market.”
Most broadcasters and newspaper
publishers are lobbying to
ease or end restrictions on cross-ownership; they say it has to be the
future
of the news business. It allows newsgathering costs to be spread across
platforms, and delivers multiple revenue streams in turn. Their
argument is
also tied to a rapidly changing media consumption market, and to the
diversity
of opinions available to the consumer with the rise of the Internet and
other
digital platforms.
The arguments against relaxing media
ownership regulations
are put forth by consumer unions and other interest groups on the
ground that
consolidation in any form inevitably leads to a lack of diversity of
opinion. Cross-ownership
limits the choices for consumers, inhibits localism and gives excessive
media
power to one entity.
Professional and workers guilds of
the communication
industry (the Screen Actors Guild and American Federation of TV and
Radio
Artists among others) would like the FCC to keep in mind the
independent voice,
and want a quarter of all prime-time programming to come from
independent
producers. The Children’s Media Policy Coalition suggested that the FCC
limit
local broadcasters to a single license per market, so that there is
enough
original programming for children. Other interest groups like the
National
Association of Black Owned Broadcasters are worried about what impact
the rules
might have on station ownership by minorities.
Deregulatory proponents see station
licensees not as “public
trustees” of the public airwaves requiring the provision of a wide
variety of
services to many different listening groups. Instead, broadcasting has
been
increasingly seen as just another business operating in a commercial
marketplace which did not need its management decisions questioned by
government
overseers, even though they are granted permission to use public
airways.
Opponents argue that deregulation violates key mandate of The
Communications
Act of 1934 which requires licensees to operate in the public interest.
Deregulation allows broadcasters to seek profits with little public
service
programming.
Clinton and Telecommunications Deregulation
The Telecommunications
Act of 1996 was the first major overhaul of US
telecommunications law in nearly 62 years, amending the Communications
Act of 1934,
and leading to media consolidation. It was approved by the 104th
Congress on January 3, 1996
and signed into law on February 8, 1996 by President Clinton, a
democrat whom some historian labeled as the best
president the Republicans ever had. The Act claimed to foster
competition, but
instead it continued the historic industry consolidation begun by
Reagan whose
actions reduced the number of major media companies from around 50 in
1983 to 10
in 1996, reducing the 10 in 1996 to 6 in 2005.
Regulation
Q
The Carter administration increased
the power of the Federal
Reserve through the Depository Institutions and Monetary Control Act
(DIDMCA)
of 1980 which was a necessary first step in ending the New Deal
restrictions
placed upon financial institutions, such as Regulation Q put in place
by the
Glass-Steagall Act of 1933 and other restrictions on banks and
financial
institutions. The populist Regulation Q imposed limits and ceilings on
bank and
savings-and-loan (S&L) interest rates to provide funds for low-risk
home
mortgages. But with financial market deregulation, Regulation Q created
incentives for US banks to do business outside the reach of US
law, launching finance globalization. London
came to dominate this offshore dollar business.
The populist Regulation Q, which
regulated for several
decades limits and ceilings on bank and savings-and-loan (S&L)
interest to
serve the home mortgage sector, was phased out completely in March
1986. Banks
were allowed to pay interest on checking account - the NOW accounts, to
lure
depositors back from the money markets. The traditional interest-rate
advantage
of the S&Ls was removed, to provide a “level playing field”,
forcing them
to take the same risk as commercial banks to survive. Congress also
lifted
restrictions on S&Ls’ commercial lending, instead of the
traditional home
mortgages, which promptly got the whole industry into trouble that
would soon
required an unprecedented government bailout of depositors, with tax
money. But
the developers who made billions from easy credit were allowed to keep
their
profits. State usury laws were unilaterally suspended by an act of
Congress in
a flagrant intrusion on state rights. Carter, the well-intentioned
populist,
left a legacy of anti-populist policies. To this day, Greenspan
continues to
argue disingenuously that sub-prime mortgages helped the poor toward
home
ownership, instead of generating obscene profit for the debt
securitization
industry.
The
Party of Lincoln
taken over by Corporate Interests
During the Reagan administration,
corporate lobbying and electoral
strategies allowed the corporate elite to wrest control of the
Republican Party,
the Party of Lincoln, from conservative populists. In the late 1980s,
supply-side
economics was promoted to allow corporate interests to dominate US
politics at
the expense of labor by arguing that the only way labor can prosper is
to let
capital achieve high returns, notwithstanding the contradiction that
high
returns on capital must come from low wages. New legislation and laws,
executive
orders, federal government rule-making, federal agency decisions, and
think-tank propaganda, etc., subsequently followed the new political
landscape,
assisting the implementation of new corporate policies and practices
emerging from
corporate headquarters rather than from the shop floor. Economists and
analysts
who challenged this voodoo theory were largely shut out of the media.
Workers
by the million were persuaded to abandon their institutional collective
defender to fend for themselves individually in the name of freedom. It
was a
freedom to see their job security eroded and wages and benefits fall
with no
recourse.
Next: Deregulation:
Global War on Labor
|