HONG KONG IN FLUX
Compradore
no more
By
Henry C K Liu
First appeared in Asia Times on
Line on July 2, 2002
Hong Kong was built on a compradore economy under British
imperialism. A few months ago, Hong Kong's acting director general of
investment promotion told delegates to the World Services Congress 2001
that Hong Kong would further enhance its role as a "Compradore City"
with China's accession to the World Trade Organization. "Upon China's
entry to the WTO, this role is going to get bigger, making it more
profitable for those who seize Hong Kong's compradore spirit and who
base their businesses in Asia's world city," the official stressed.
A compradore was a native servant employed as head of the
native staff and, as agent, by foreign trading houses in China during
its shameful semi-colonial history. Imperialist interests in colonial
markets mediated through compradores. As a class, the compradore
bourgeoisie is despised by socialist revolutionaries as well as by
members of the national bourgeoisie. The compradore has no positive
economic function in a regime of free and fair trade. Ideology and
national pride aside, in the era of globalization and e-commerce
through instant communication, where efficiency is achieved through the
elimination of intermediaries, a compradore economy is a dying breed.
Economic nationalism will put the final nail in the compardore's
coffin.
The future of Hong Kong as a compradore economy can be summed
up quite simply: non-existent. This is not nit-picking, for it
illustrates a basic flaw in Hong Kong's image of its future.
Monday, July 1, marked the fifth anniversary of Hong Kong's
return to Chinese sovereignty from British rule. On that day, Tung
Chee-hwa, the chief executive of the Hong Kong Special Autonomous
Region (SAR), began his second and final five-year term with a newly
appointed cabinet in a reformed government structure of political
accountability riding herd over an apolitical civil service. Five years
earlier, many in Hong Kong, infested with the compradore spirit,
exemplified by the madame chief secretary (Anson Chan) of the holdover
colonial civil service at that time, echoing US neo-liberal propaganda,
openly worried about undue Chinese interference on Hong Kong's "free
market" success, harping on the importance of human rights, democracy
and rule of law, none of which had been particularly inherent under
British colonialism as indispensable ingredients of Hong Kong's freak
prosperity, all in which China was pictured as being deficient.
On July 2, 1997, the day after the historic return of Hong
Kong to China, the Asian financial crises began in Thailand. Those in
the new SAR government in charge of economic policy complacently
proclaimed that the "fundamentals" of the Hong Kong economy were sound
and that all that was needed was to maintain Hong Kong's
free-enterprise tradition to ride through the passing storm. Oblivious
to the structural and systemic nature of the developing financial
crises, Hong Kong even contributed US$1 billion from its
foreign-exchange reserves to the International Monetary Fund (IMF) to
help contain the unfolding crisis within Thailand. The uninformed
hubris was answered by devastating contagion hitting the Hong Kong
economy by October 1997.
The irony is that Hong Kong, which tirelessly flaunts its
"freedom", religiously chanting neo-liberal slogans by rote, is now
looking to China as the hope of its economic future, never questioning
why China, which has been labeled derisively as less "free" and with an
underdeveloped regime of commercial law by many in self-satisfied Hong
Kong, is the only growth economy in East Asia in the midst of global
recession, while "free" Hong Kong has been stuck in economic decline
for half a decade. All the condescending accolades of "freedom" Hong
Kong received from foreign conservative organizations such as the
Heritage Foundation, Freedom House and the American Enterprise
Institute have not been of much help in convincing global capital
heading for China to bypass Shanghai in favor of Hong Kong or
transnational corporations in search of the China market to locate
their regional headquarters in Hong Kong instead of Shanghai.
GE, the world largest conglomerate, has just announced that
it will move the regional headquarters of its plastics division from
Tokyo to Shanghai, at the same time downsizing its operation in Hong
Kong. All transnational corporations now have localization programs in
China, staffed with mainlanders with masters of business administration
(MBAs) from US universities who speak better Mandarin than most
graduates from Hong Kong, where Cantonese is the preferred Chinese
language. These corporations have no need for Hong Kong compradores.
Hong Kong recognizes that it must restructure its economy,
but it is not clear that the SAR government is prepared to accept that
economic restructure can only be achieved through strong government
policy. Hong Kong continues to cling to the myth of an anti-statist
past, for fear that any hint of industrial policy or government
interference with the market would displease US neo-liberals and bring
down their political wrath of reduced access to US markets.
Yet it is undeniable that Hong Kong's current
dysfunctionalities had been caused by British colonial policy disguised
as free-market forces. For one and a half centuries, the British ruled
Hong Kong for the benefit of the British Empire, not to promote human
rights, nor democracy, nor free markets, all of which were slogans
recently co-opted as Cold War rhetoric to justify continuing colonial
rule in an era of national liberation. To correct these
dysfunctionalities, bold government leadership with political courage
is needed.
The performance of the SAR government has not enjoyed
overwhelming popular approval because the public expects strong
political leadership and bold policies and programs to deal with Hong
Kong's economic woes, while the government is fixated in its passive
role as faithful defender of free-market fundamentalism.
Hong Kong set up a Commission on Strategic Development in
1998 to look decades beyond 1997 to see what sort of community and
economy Hong Kong should be working toward. The commission report, with
a title sounding like a second-rate Madison Avenue ad campaign
("Bringing the Vision to Life - Hong Kong's Long-Term Development Needs
and Goals") identified four strategic themes. One theme is to
strengthen links with mainland China, in particular the prosperous
economies of Guangzhou, Shenzhen, Zhuhai and Macau, Hong Kong's
neighbors in the Pearl River Delta. The other three are to enhance
competitiveness, improve the quality of life and to reinforce Hong
Kong's identity and image to create a world-class business and living
environment in Hong Kong. The vision is to make Hong Kong a leading
world city, on par with New York and London, as well as to strengthen
its unique position as a major international city in China.
Yet the former madame chief secretary of the civil service,
well trained by the last British governor of Hong Kong (Chris Patten -
now of European Commission fame), repeatedly and forcefully warned
against turning Hong Kong into a Chinese city. It is a peculiar
posture, because New York or London do not feel the need to renounce
their national identity in order to be international centers. Typical
of her compradore spirit, Anson Chan was bent on being more Western
than her British masters. To attract tourists, a Hong Kong Disneyland
is to open in 2005. Surely very few Westerners would come to Hong Kong
to visit Disneyland. Thus the target tourist population would be mainly
Asians, mostly Chinese, an irony that apparently escaped the lady.
Hong Kong has merged its exchanges and clearing houses to
make them more efficient and competitive. The new exchange is forging
strategic alliances with other stock exchanges to capitalize on its
location in the East Asian time zone. Hong Kong opened a growth
enterprise market that is modeled on the Nasdaq to help new companies
with a promising future to raise capital. Hong Kong's
telecommunications sector has been liberalized, following global
trends, with similar controversial outcomes. The unfolding global
telecom debt crisis will not spare Hong Kong, as the Internet and
dotcom bubble burst did not spare Hong Kong. The ill-conceived
CyberPort will be a white elephant memorial to Hong Kong's high-tech
fantasy. No economy can develop a high-tech sector without a research
and development program supported by national defense. Hong Kong's
market culture has been focused on property development and
labor-intensive manufacturing as a result of government policy.
Much talk is heard about offering high-value-added services,
and building a forward-looking community that utilizes innovation and
technology. Yet Hong Kong has the highest concentration of family-owned
and family-run enterprises anywhere, and they are not particularly
known for innovation. In corporate governance, Hong Kong remains a
developing region. With all the fanfare about being a mecca for free
markets, Hong Kong does not have a rule-based competition policy.
To its credit, the SAR government has committed an enormous
amount of resources to the education sector, aiming to create the
best-educated and most well-rounded generation of youth in the history
of Hong Kong. Yet Hong Kong tolerates a protracted and serious brain
drain to the West, mostly to the US, where many of Hong Kong's
brightest have gone for university education and stayed on because they
were not interested in a career in real estate or in joining a family
business. Every week, some recruitment delegation from various regions
of China visits the United States to entice Chinese students,
scientists and professionals with promising opportunities in China.
Few, if any, delegations ever came from Hong Kong. Moreover, a massive
brain drain from Hong Kong to China is currently in process.
Hong Kong commits enormous resources to infrastructure
building. Yet much of the infrastructure serves merely to manage the
overcrowding caused by exorbitant land costs. Chek Lap Kok, Hong Kong's
$20-billion airport, Britain's parting gift to Anglo-American
contractors, has great aspirations to be a regional logistics hub, and
the government has said that it will invest even more toward that goal.
But foreign air-cargo companies are put off by the inability to do
onward shipping from the airport. The problem stems from the
government's attempts to protect Cathay Pacific, the airline owned by
one of Hong Kong's oldest conglomerates. Hong Kong needs to liberalize
its air-cargo aviation regime if it wants to be a logistics center for
the modern high-tech and high-value-added world. Also, the
over-investment has produced world-class facilities that must also
charge world-class rates, leaving Hong Kong with a disadvantaged price
competitiveness.
Hong Kong cannot independently improve its environmental
standards without close regional cooperation. There are signs that the
whole region has not faced up to the real cost of environmental cleanup
and protection.
The chief executive has proposed to the central government to
devise specific policies in support of Hong Kong's position as an
international financial center, a trade and logistic center, and
tourism center. Specifically, Hong Kong has asked Beijing to recognize
and utilize Hong Kong's established competitive advantages fully when
it makes overall planning for economic development, infrastructure and
other large-scale investments. Hong Kong has it backward. It is Hong
Kong that must adjust to China's developmental needs, not the other way
around.
The chief executive also has proposed the establishment of a
free-trade-area arrangement between Hong Kong and the mainland that
will provide greater opportunity to Hong Kong businesses and
professionals. With this arrangement, Hong Kong hopes to explore fully
the potential for greater economic cooperation within the Pearl River
Delta area. This is of course a logical move. Yet Article 114 of the
Basic Law sets Hong Kong as a free port without tariffs unless
otherwise prescribed by law, and Article 115 sets a policy of free
trade, while Article 116 defines Hong Kong as a separate customs
territory. These articles, so vigorously fought for before 1997, are
now impeding Hong Kong's development.
Still, the most serious challenge facing Hong Kong as an
international finance center is to find its proper place in the global
financial system. The global financial crises caused by US dollar
hegemony that hit Asia on July 2, 1997, is far from over. The
fundamentals behind the crises, developed over a decade of unregulated
finance globalization, have not been addressed at their roots. Most of
the measures adopted so far by the Group of Seven (G7) industrialized
nations, of which the US is the leader, pulling the G22 nations by
their reluctant noses, have to do with bailing out G7 transnational
banks on their foreign loans, and pushing down interest rates to keep
global stock markets artificially high, indicators of fleeting
financial robustness but usually mis-indicators of fundamental economic
health. Wall Street called it the Goldilocks economy, where bad news
was interpreted as good and visa versa by naive investors led by
unprincipled analysts in collusion with fraudulent chief executive
officers. Well, Goldilocks has been abruptly awakened by the bears
demanding to know who has been eating their porridge and sleeping in
their beds.
Asia has experienced sudden financial collapse not because
the goods produced in Asia are suddenly unmarketable worldwide, or
Asian management has suddenly become so inept as to incur unforeseen
losses in Asian companies. It is certainly not the inevitable outcome
of alleged inherent defects in Asian values, as Western analysts claim.
Rather, the collapse is the result of abrupt and recurring ruptures in
the unregulated global system of financial markets.
Beginning in the early 1960s, with the growth of Euromarkets
where banks in one European country could take deposits and make loans
in currencies of other countries, the tight controls of the
international flow of capital set up by the Bretton Woods system of
fixed exchange rates after World War II were in effect bypassed.
Drawing lessons from the 1930s Depression, economic thinking prevalent
immediately after the war had deemed international capital flow
undesirable or unnecessary. When the fixed-exchange-rate system finally
broke down in the early 1970s, the developed countries abandoned
capital controls officially. In the late 1980s, many developing
countries followed suit.
By the end of the last decade, daily turnover of foreign
exchange grew more than 100-fold to over $2 trillion from $190 billion
at the beginning of the decade. By 1996, some $350 billion of private
capital flowed into emerging markets, a sevenfold increase in six
years. For the past two decades, technical imbalances between interest
rates set by different central banks for funds in different currencies
distorted capital flow around the world. The resultant inflow of
capital into Asia through inter-linked financial markets around the
globe outstripped the region's viable absorption rate. Financial
institutions took advantage of low cost funds denominated in currencies
of select countries, namely Japan, Germany and the United States, to
make loans at higher interest rates denominated in local Asian
currencies. These institutions sought to strategically profit from
recurring technical imbalances in global finance by assuming currency
risks. Economists name this development as international arbitrage on
the principle of open interest parity. In banking parlance, this type
of activity is known as "carry trade".
This manipulative speculation was by no means limited to
emerging economies. Corporations based in developed economies routinely
engaged in global financial and stock-market speculation at the expense
of sound production strategies. The public announcement of plans to
open new factories in Asia predictably lifted share values in home
markets, regardless that such factories risked being loss-makers, for
the loss would be more than covered by the increase in market
capitalization. Corporate borrowers in Asia, attracted by low rates in
some foreign currency loans, have also assumed currency risks, at times
even bypassing local banks to borrow directly in debt markets overseas.
Borrowers, anticipating asset inflation brought by run-away growth,
also succumbed to the irresistible temptation of borrowing short-term
to finance long-term projects, thus adding to the risk they assumed.
Simultaneously, many Asian banks have taken local-currency deposits at
low saving rates (in Hong Kong at times at negative interest rates) to
invest overseas in risky foreign-currency instruments yielding higher
returns, engaging in carry trade. Local banks in turn replenished the
depleted local capital pool with low-cost foreign-currency loans from
international banks, taking on both economic and currency risks.
Borrowing low and lending high is the basic business of
banks, and there is nothing wrong with it if the activities occur
within a well-regulated market of a bank's domicile community. With the
advent of global banking, however, the unregulated internationalization
of finance has created perilous systemic stress. Banks began to act as
international loan brokers, profiting from interest-rate spreads
between local and foreign funds, often booking the risk premium added
to weak currency interest rates as legitimate loan profits. These banks
also began to maximize their profits by maximizing loan volume,
abrogating their traditional economic function as responsible financial
pillars of local economies to ensure the productive allocation of
capital. In time, local banks de-coupled their business self-interest
from the economic impacts of their loans on the local economies,
because they hedged the risk in such loans by passing it to overseas
hedge funds which became the real loan originators. Western and
Japanese international banks in turn provided funds to the local broker
banks in Asia whose credit ratings were considered acceptable because
the borrowers' exposures were hedged by instruments designed to
transfer risk to other international institutions. The global
overcapacity in manufacturing is the direct result of this unregulated
financial market.
In effect, the widespread transfer of business risks into
currency risks forced the governments of the affected currencies to
become involuntary lenders of last resort. This is the real effect of
Hong Kong's and other Asian currency pegs to the US dollar. China is
relatively insulated from the financial crisis mainly because the yuan
is not fully and freely convertible.
Hedging does not eliminate risk, it merely passes risk along
to other parties. In fact, complex hedging schemes, with the effect of
reducing the risk exposure of individual lenders and inflating the
credit worthiness of the hedged individual borrowers, when widely
practiced, actually increase systemic risk exposure, initially of
regional financial systems and ultimately of the global system. Yet the
soundness of financial institutions continues to be assessed singularly
within national borders, while financial markets have become
intricately linked globally. A poor credit rating seldom means the
denial of credit. It only means a higher interest rate, which actually
attracts more eager lenders who rationalize that the high risk has been
compensated for by the increased rate.
Through extensive hedging, private financial risks have been
largely socialized globally. The ingenious layering of protection
against risk, while providing comfort to individual players, buys such
comfort at the expense of the security of the total global system. At
some point, the strained circular chain breaks at the weakest link and
panic sets in. For Asia, that break occurred in Thailand on July 1,
1997.
Because of this circular system of global hedging, the
economic crises in Asia inevitably spread worldwide. The regional
crises, each with unique local characteristics, are merely early
symptoms of a ticking global time bomb constructed out of the complex
calculus of interlinked financial markets in which countless individual
credit risks are legally masked as sound transactions through
sophisticated hedging. Derivatives, financial instruments which derive
their value from other underlying financial instruments or benchmarks
such as stock indexes or exchange rates, are the cards in the fragile
house of cards built by a financial specialty known as structured
finance.
International finance in recent years has been saturated with
disastrous and scandalous abuses that clearly and repeatedly epitomize
the deficiencies of the unregulated global interlinking of financial
markets. Speculators have been blamed for precipitating the run on
currencies that started the financial crises. Yet speculation and risk
management are two sides of the same coin. At the opposite end of a
prudent hedge, a speculator is required. Structured finance enables the
unbundling of risk for marketing to different levels of risk takers,
creating the illusion that risk is neutralized when it is merely
distributed imperceptibly throughout the financial system. In a
structurally flawed system, perfectly honorable businessmen or
institutions, individually normally true to high ethical and financial
standards, can unwittingly participate in systemic games of dubious
value.
Data on the initial six months of the Asian financial crises
show that currency hedging individually by sophisticated businesses and
alert government bodies, domestic and foreign, as protective measures
against foreign-exchange exposures in both debt and revenue, had been
mostly responsible for the sudden currency turmoil in the region. In
international finance, a game of musical chairs in financial risk is in
full force in which the players are handcuffed together through
interlinking hedges between parties unknown to each other. This game
can cause serious systemic rupture when the music stops. Yet world
leaders continue to deny its danger.
A good part of the responsibility of the Asian financial
crises is attributable to international banks not facing up to their
lender liability, a legal concept holding lenders liable for damages if
they knowingly lend beyond any borrower's capacity to handle the loan.
It is convenient for Western creditors to point fingers at Asian crony
capitalism and lack of transparency, but such practices, albeit
undesirable, are not unique to Asia and were certainly not unknown to
lenders when the bad loans were made. Having been permanent cultural
features in many parts of the world, including Asia, such practices
cannot be the direct cause of the region's sudden financial collapse,
any more than its economic success in the recent past.
Instead of focusing on correcting the structural defects of
the unregulated globalization of financial markets, IMF rescue packages
have been devious vehicles for wholesale foreign control of wounded
Asian economies. IMF "off the shelf" rescue approaches have exacerbated
the financial crises in Asia. Moreover, the austerity measures demanded
by IMF economists who are insensitive to local political realities have
turned the economic turmoil into detonators of political instability
throughout the region.
A fundamental problem in world trade finance is the excessive
weight foreign-exchange markets assign to the size of a country's
foreign-exchange reserves as an indicator of economic health and credit
worthiness, despite general recognition by economists that the validity
of this yardstick ended with the age of mercantilism a century ago.
Yet, despite claims of scientific determinism, financial markets are
not free of political bias. And this residual focus on foreign-exchange
reserves is not applied evenly to all economies. Curiously, the United
States, the world's largest debtor nation (carrying $20,000 of
sovereign debt per capita), with two-thirds of all US currency being
held overseas, with severe budget deficits and a history of volatile
fluctuations in the floating exchange rates of its fiat currency, is
considered the safest haven from economic turmoil because of its
perceived political stability and the size of its domestic economy. On
the opposite end, Hong Kong, with its huge foreign-exchange reserves,
perennial budgetary surpluses prior to the Asian financial crises, and
zero sovereign debt, has repeatedly seen its solidly backed currency
under relentless attack in a market artificially fixed by a peg to the
US dollar.
The reason for this is simple. Hong Kong's
linked-exchange-rate mechanism is itself an open admission of no
confidence in its own currency. With a linked-exchange-rate mechanism,
Hong Kong pledges to exchange Hong Kong dollars at a fixed rate to the
US dollar and holds 110 percent equivalent US dollars in reserve for
each Hong Kong dollar in circulation. This currency peg requires local
interest rates to track US rates, plus a country risk premium that is
determined in part by the market's view of the economic viability of
the peg rate. That viability has no economic basis. It is based
entirely on arbitrary political will. Thus, the wider the gap between
the official exchange rate and the market's judgment of the economic
value of the HK dollar, the higher would be the cost of maintaining the
peg. The Hong Kong government also holds most of its foreign exchange
reserves in US dollar denominated instruments, in excess of its
trade-weighted needs.
These arrangements represent a loud and clear declaration
that the US dollar is a sounder currency than the Hong Kong dollar. One
can expect such a discriminatory attitude from the former British
colonial government, but one is at a loss to understand why a new Hong
Kong SAR under Chinese sovereignty would feel the need to hang on to
such a self-defacing political posture. Hong Kong should be reminded
that the US dollar, despite unjustified perceptions of its soundness,
is only as solid as the true state of the US economy at any given time,
and at this moment it is not very sound.
In 1995, after the US Federal Reserve started to increase
interest rates in 1994 and sharply curtailed its own purchase of
treasury bills, triggering the Mexico peso crisis and a subsequent US
slowdown, the Bank of Japan initiated a program to buy $100 billion of
US treasuries. China bought $80 billion. Hong Kong and Singapore bought
$22 billion each. South Korea, Malaysia, Thailand, Indonesia and the
Philippines together bought $30 billion. The Asian purchase totaled
$260 billion from 1994 to 1997, the entire increase in foreign-held US
dollar reserves. These recycled dollars pushed up stock prices in the
US, forming part of what Fed chairman Alan Greenspan referred to as
"irrational exuberance".
A sharp correction of the stock markets accompanied by an
abrupt slowdown of the US economy was a matter of when and not if, and
it began in late 2000 with the bottom nowhere in sight. Also, the euro
will pose a direct challenge to the US dollar as the preferred currency
for international trade. The financial world is in the process of
shifting from a dollar-centered system to a bipolar dollar-euro system.
Just like the postwar corrections in US markets in 1971-73, 1978-79,
1985-87, which critically stalled the US economy because the
contributing currency overvaluations were permitted to go too far and
for too long, the coming correction which has apparently finally begun
after much delay, will have equally if not more severe adverse economic
consequences.
This means that when the Asian economies finally are working
themselves out from the damages of the crises that began in 1997, the
US economy stalls and the US dollar falls in value, ending the US as a
market of last resort and the dollar as a safe haven investment. Five
years after the 1929 crash, US president Franklin D Roosevelt was
forced in 1934 to ease monetary policy through a 59 percent devaluation
of the US dollar against gold.
The global financial crises that began in Mexico in 1995 and
hit Asia in 1997 were not mere passing storms or cyclical phases. They
are the opening acts of a historic restructuring of the global economic
system in which the stakes are very high. Economic globalization
requires enlightened nationalism to keep it fair and just. China has
shown signs that it is becoming aware of this fact. Hong Kong as part
of China, despite the peculiar "one country, two systems" arrangement,
cannot be independent of Chinese national interests.
Next: Pegged Down
|