The Real Interest Rate Conundrum
By
Henry C.K. Liu
Part I: The Real Interest
Rate Conundrum
Part II: Currency Devaluation
Depresses Wages Globally
This article
appeared in AToL on June 13, 2007 as How currency devaluation destroys
wealth
In today’s financial
world, a liquidity
boom produces rising nominal or face value in return on investment
(ROI) with
an increasingly hollow economy in two ways: 1) by devaluing all
currencies
against real assets and 2) by keeping down wages and worker benefits
around the
globe.
Thus while all currencies devalue
steadily but not at the same pace, all of them devalue faster against
real
assets and slower against labor cost because wage adjustments tend to
lag
behind both real and nominal inflation rates. This translates directly
into low
real valuation for labor, structurally constraining growth of demand to
fall
behind growth of supply. This in turn leads to an overcapacity economy
of
declining consumer purchasing power. Neo-classical economists call this
the
business cycle which Keynesians assert that it must be countered with
demand
management through full employment with rising wages supported by
deficit
financing in down cycles.
The
Laws of Overcapacity
The first law of overcapacity is that it
is deflationary (falling market prices of assets) which in turn
requires
falling wages to maintain corporate earnings. The
second law of overcapacity is that it
discourages new plant
expansion so that existing capital assets appreciate in market value in
nominal
terms as liquidity increases, causing the stock markets to rise even
though
their economic value remains stagnant.
But the laws of overcapacity naturally
lead to a downward economic spiral that ends in depression. Moreover,
socio-political stability requires nominal wages to continue to rise
above
inflation. Thus the convenient monetarist solution is to allow stealth
but real
devaluation of currencies against real assets, but with a slower
devaluation rate
against the value of labor, giving wage earners the false feeling of
gaining
while actually losing. The global regime of declining currency value is
one
that will lead to a new form of slavery, despite a rise in living
standards
from higher labor productivity and resource utilization as a result of
technological progress.
Universal
Currency Devaluation Masked by Exchange Rate Regime
Universal currency devaluation is masked
by an exchange rate regime in which currencies rise and fall unevenly
against
each other around the benchmark US dollar as the prime reserve currency
while
all currencies fall against hard assets in unison but at different
rates due to
varying local conditions. The uneven rates of currency devaluation
present
windows of profit opportunity for arbitrageurs in the global foreign
exchange
and financial markets. A network of interlocking asset bubbles then
grows
around the world as a result of dollar hegemony and the emergence of
deregulated
global currency and financial markets, jumping over national borders,
fuelled
by a general devaluation of all currencies while the trading public is
distracted to focus on the relative exchange value of one currency
against
another.
Thus while both the dollar and the euro
steadily fall, Europeans are comforted by seeing their currency rise
against
the dollar in recent years when in fact the euro has merely been
temporarily
falling at a slower rate than the dollar. As the dollar, the prime
benchmark
reserve currency for trade and finance, devalues against assets, the
exchange
rate regime in the current international finance architecture will
eventually
drag all currencies down with the dollar, lest the trading partners of
the US
should find themselves saddled with trade penalties associated with
inoperative
exchange rates.
A
Confused Public
The general public is further confused by
uncertainty about whether a rising currency is good or bad for them.
They are
told to rejoice when their currency falls as the goods they produce
will sell
in larger quantity because they can be bought with less money by
foreigners,
even their own income per unit of production will fall and they
themselves will
be crowded out of restaurants and shops in their own hometowns by
suddenly
richer foreign tourists. Ironically, while any normal citizen should
find the
prospect of receiving less money for the same amount of product he/she
produces
unappetizing, policymakers insist that there is no alternative
systemically. In
the mean time, the rich in the world get richer from declining wages
worldwide.
All the economies of the world are
competing in global markets by pushing their domestic wages and worker
benefits
down in search of globalized “growth”. The global market has turned
into an
arena for universal voluntary slavery to serve global capital.
Wicksell’s
Ideas Obsolete
Wicksell’s idea of fighting inflation by
pegging interest rate to ROI, operative under industrial capitalism, is
problematic in finance capitalism because of the emergence of
structured
finance in which the traditional discounted rate of return for
industrial
investment tend to be overwhelmed by astronomical returns from
financial
manipulation routinely expected of hedge funds and private equity
firms. To
fight stealth inflation from currency devaluation, Wicksell’s notion of
pegging
interest rate to ROI in structured finance would set interest rate so
high as
to make the sky-high Volcker rate of 19.93% pegged to money supply look
tame.
Further, in Wicksell’s time, there were
no exchange rate issues as there was no foreign exchange market since
the
reserve currency was based on the gold standard with other currencies
adopting
fixed exchange rates against it and cross border movement of funds was
strictly
regulated and current accounts between trading nations were settled in
gold
regularly through adjustment of national accounts in the Bank of
International
Settlement. Domestic interest rates had no direct immediate effect on
the
exchange value of a country’s currency. Today, domestic interest rates
have a
bearing on currency exchange rates, albeit increasingly less directly.
High
domestic interest rates will push a currency’s exchange rate upward,
hurting a
country’s current account balance, worsening domestic inflation, even
though
this relationship is increasingly obscured by the decoupling of nominal
interest rate from the real interest rate and the decoupling of
exchange rate
between currencies from the real value of all currencies as derivative
of a fiat
dollar as the main reserve currency.
The Lessons of 1987
The 1987 crash was
unleashed by the sudden collapse of the
safety dam of portfolio insurance, a hedging strategy made possible by
the new
option pricing theory advanced by Noble Laureates Merton/Scholes.
Institutional
investors found it possible to better managing risk by protecting their
portfolios from unexpected losses with positions in stock index
futures. Any
fall in stock prices can be compensated by selling futures bought when
stock
prices were higher.
This strategy, while
operative for each individual
portfolio, actually caused the entire market to collapse from the
dynamics of
automatic herd-selling of futures. Investors could afford to take
greater risks
in rising markets because portfolio insurance offered a disciplined way
of
avoiding risk in declines, albeit only individually. As some portfolio
insurers
sold and market prices fell precipitously, the computer programs of
other
insurers then triggered further sales causing further declines which in
turn
caused the first group of insurers to sell even more stock and so on,
in a high
speed downward spiral. This in turn
generated other sell orders from the same sources and the market
experienced a computer-generated
meltdown.
The 1987 crash
provided clear empirical evidence of the
structural flaw in market fundamentalism which is the belief that the
optimum
common welfare is only achievable through a market equilibrium created
by the
effect of countless individual decisions of all market participants
each
seeking to maximize his own private gain, and that such market
equilibrium
should not be distorted by any collective measures in the name of the
common
good. Aggregate individual decisions and actions in unorganized unison
can and
often do turn into systemic crises that are detrimental to the common
good. Unregulated free markets can
quickly become failed markets. Markets do not simply grow naturally
after a
spring rain. Markets are artificial constructs designed collectively by
key
participants who agree to play by certain rules. All markets are
planned with
the aim of eliminating any characteristic of being free for all
operations.
Free market is as much a fantasy as free love.
In response to the
1987 crash, the US Federal Reserve under
its newly installed chairman, Alan Greenspan, with merely nine weeks in
the
powerful office, immediately flooded the banking system with new
reserves, by
having the Fed Open Market Committee (FOMC) buy massive quantities of
government securities from the market.
He announced the day following the crash that the Fed would “serve as a
source of liquidity to support the economic and financial
system.” Greenspan created US$12 billion of new bank
reserves by buying up government securities from the market, the
proceeds from
which would enter the banking system.
The $12 billion
injection of “high-power money” in one day
caused the FFR to fall by 75 basis points and halted the financial
panic,
though it did not cure the financial problem, which caused the economy
to
plunge into a recession that persisted for five subsequent years.
High-power money
injected into the banking system enables
banks to create more bank money through multiple credit-recycling,
lending
repeatedly the same funds minus the amount of required bank reserves at
each
turn. At 10% reserve requirement, $12
billion of new high power money could generate in theory up to $120
billions of
new bank money in the form of recycled bank loans from new deposits
from
borrowers.
The Brady Commission
investigation of the 1987 crash shows
that on October 19, 1987,
portfolio insurance trades in S&P 500 index futures and NYSE stocks
that
crashed the market amounted to only $6 billion by a few large traders,
out of a
market trading total of $42 billion. The Fed’s liquidity injection of
$120
billion was three times the market trading total and 20 times the
trades
executed by portfolio insurance.
Yet post-mortem
analyses of the 1987 crash suggest that
though portfolio insurance strategies were designed to be interest rate
neutral, declining FFR was actually causing financial firms that used
these
strategies to lose money from exchange rate effects. The belated
awareness of
this effect caused many institutions that had not understood the full
dynamics
of the strategies to shut down their previously highly profitable bond
arbitrage units. This move later led to the migratory birth of new,
stand-alone
hedge funds such as Long Term Capital Management (LTCM) which continued
to
apply similar gighly leverage strategies for spectacular trading profit
of over
70% return on equity that eventual led it to the edge of bankruptcy
when Russia
unexpectedly defaulted of its dollar bonds in the summer of 1998. The
Fed had
to orchestrate a private-sector creditor bailout of LTCM to limit
systemic
damage to the financial markets. The net effect was to extend the
liquidity
bubble further that migrated from distressed sector to healthy sector.
The 1987 crash
reflected a stock market bubble burst the
liquidity cure for which led to a property bubble that when burst in
turn
caused the Savings and Loan crisis. The Financial Institutions Reform
Recovery
and Enforcement Act (FIRREA) was enacted by the US Congress in August,
1989, to
bail out the wayward thrift industry in the S&L crisis by creating
the
Resolution Trust Corporation (RTC) to take over failed savings banks
and
disposed of their distressed assets at fire sale prices. The
Federal Reserve reacted to the S&L
crisis with further massive injection of liquidity into the commercial
banking
system, lowering the FFR from its high of 9.86% reached on May 10, 1989
to 3%
on September 4, 1992, making the real rate near zero until February 4,
1994. It was too late to help George Bush, Sr. in his second term
election in November, 1992, but it gave the Clinton
era a liquidity boom. Since there were few assets worth investing in a
down
market plagued by overcapacity, most of the new money went into
relatively
low-yield bonds. This resulted in a bond
bubble by 1993, which then burst in 1994 when the Fed finally started
to raise
the short-term rate, reaching 6% on February 1, 1995.
By 1994, Greenspan
was already riding on the back of the
debt tiger from which he could not dismount without being devoured by
it. The
DJIA was below 4,000 in 1994 and rose steadily to a bubble of near
12,000 by
2000, a 300% rise, while Greenspan raised the FFR seven times from 3%
to 6%
between February 4, 1994, and February 1, 1995, a 100% rise, to try to
curb
"irrational exuberance" in the stock market, and kept it above 5%
until October 15, 1998, after contagion from the 1997 Asian Financial
Crisis
hit Wall Street, when the Fed reversed course on interest rates.
By the mid-1990s,
excess liquidity had fueled a worldwide
equity rally that found its way into the Asian emerging markets, where
it fed
an unprecedented bubble of easy money in the form of undervalued
currencies
pegged to a falling US dollar. When the Asian emerging market
bubble
crashed abruptly on July 2, 1997 as the Thai central bank suddenly ran
out of
foreign exchange reserves in a matter of days trying to maintain its
unsustainable currency peg, followed by the Russian debt crisis in
1998, all
the major central banks of the world reacted yet again by pumping even
more
liquidity into the global banking system, exacerbating a new wave of
global
decline in currency value. During this period, the dollar never rose in
real
value although its exchange rate with Asia currencies
rose because the Asian currencies were falling in value faster than the
dollar.
Confusing Money with
Wealth
Money itself is not
wealth, only a generally accepted
measuring unit of wealth. Liquidity, the flooding of the financial
system with
money, does not necessarily add wealth.
Liquidity accelerates financial transactions that can create or destroy
wealth depending on the terms of exchange. In the days of industrial
capitalism, wealth was created by the creation of productive hard
assets, while
in finance capitalism wealth is created only by earnings. Where as
wealth is
increased by more production in industrial capitalism, earnings in
finance
capitalism increase only money income which only adds wealth if the
purchasing
power of money does not decline. When asset prices rise without real
expansion
of the purchasing power of earnings, money is simply devalued while the
nominal
value of assets increases as real wealth remains stagnant or even
declines.
Initially, this
flood of money that began in 1994 inflated
another bond bubble, which popped viciously in 1999. Then, more
liquidity
released by the Fed boosted equity prices further and provided the fuel
for the
enormous tech stock bubble of 1999 and early 2000.
The Fed’s Money
Creation Addiction
The first
three years of the 21st century saw a world-wide equity
market crash
followed by a recession plagued by global overcapacity,
over-indebtedness, and
over-leveraging. And the response of central banks was always
more
liquidity through low interest rates in relation to return on capital,
which
helped pump up the bond bubble in 2003 and supported artificial rallies
in
housing prices, equities, commodity prices, higher corporate debt
without
changing debt/equity ratios and mushrooming emerging markets,
particularly
China. Fools were calling it a US-led
recovery.
A Bubble within a Bubble
Once the
genie of excess liquidity is out of the bottle, it is almost inevitable
that a
bigger genie will have to be let out of a bigger bottle to keep the
ongoing
bubble from bursting, to avoid the nasty consequences of a burst bubble
for the
financial system and the real economy. Central banks round the
world, led
by the US Federal Reserve, despite their pivotal role in helping to
create
financial bubbles, nevertheless declare that bubbles cannot be
anticipated and
nothing can be done to prevent them, but central bankers comfort
markets by
claiming magical power to handle the destructive consequences of
bubbles,
through a one-note monetary policy of short-term rate cuts to inject
fresh
liquidity, to save a bursting bubble by creating a bigger bubble. With
structured finance, bubbles can be created by endogenous liquidity and
bubbles
about to burst are expected by be rescued by central bank intervention.
And even if
central banks reacted to asset bubbles by raising short-term interest
rates,
the extent of the rate hikes needed to reverse asset prices in times of
exuberance might be so large that it would destabilize the real economy
worse
than a bubble burst would. This view is
supported by the experience Greenspan had in his battle against
“irrational
exuberance.” While declaring that
central banks cannot prevent bubbles, the Fed has admitted more than
once that
it sees as one of the roles of a central bank the support of the market
value
of financial assets, however inflated. Instead of being the guardian
against
moral hazard, the Fed has become the promoter of moral hazard.
Good Economic News Bad for Dysfunctional Markets
A market
anomaly is thus created in which equity prices rise in response to what
normally would be considered bad news for the real economy, such as
falling
home sales, because the market then would expect the Fed will lower
short-term
rates, causing equity prices to rise, even though home mortgage rates
are tied
to 10-year Treasuries rates. Conversely, equity prices would fall in
response to
what normally would be considered good economic news such as rising
home sales
because that would cause the Fed to raise short-term rates which really
do not
have any direct connection to home finance. This
is because the market knows that in a
bubble about to burst, good
news of further expansion is bad news.
US Debt Structured as Russian Matryoshka
Nesting Dolls
US financial assets
have been built not only on debt, but on
debt recycled at high velocity. It is a form of turbo debt in which one
dollar of
debt can act as equity to finance over $100 of credit through
sequential
leveraged financing and leveraged securitization. Borrowers in turn
become
lenders who themselves lend borrowed money. Massive financial energy is
released through chain reaction of a tiny amount of equity.
Debt is not
intrinsically objectionable if it is adequately
collateralized by real assets, and the proceeds are invested to
increase real
national income above what is needed to service the debt. But
turbo debt by definition is generated by
practically no equity. And if debt is serviced mostly by the wealth
effect of
debt-propelled asset appreciation, a bubble is in the making. The
so-called air-ball financing enabled the
telecom bubble of the 1990s, when it was widely used in financing
telecom
expansion in the 1990s. Air-ball financing involves the use of
unrealistically
anticipated future earnings as collateral for financing
over-investments in
hope of generating those earnings. A
housing bubble exists because houses are being financed and refinanced
by
full-value mortgages collateralized only by the anticipated continuing
rise in
home prices. A liquidity boom generates asset bubbles because liquidity
is not
wealth, only an illusion of wealth. And the rise in asset prices beyond
the
growth of GDP is really a decline in currency value. A market rise of
40%
against a GDP growth of 3% translates into a currency depreciation of
37% in a
year.
Debt Securitization Blurs
the distinction between Debt and Equity
The pervasive
securitization of debt accompanied by a
complex network of hedging blurs the all important dividing line
between debtor
and creditor, and allows an economy to borrow from itself, not just
against its
future, but against its current and less sophisticated debt, not for
productive
investment to generate real wealth, but for financial manipulation to
achieve
virtual profit. The use of debt as collateral for more sophisticated
debt has
characteristics of a bubble. The broad
unbundling of risk to maximize transactional surplus (profit)
ultimately leads
to the socialization of risk (transferring unit risk into systemic
risk) while
the privatization of the resultant profit remains a sacred
prerequisite. This
mal-distribution of virtual wealth exacerbates both the risk and the
effect of
a bubble by make a bubble inside a bubble.
The Bank of
International Settlement “Lamfalussy
Report" defines systemic risk as “the risk that the illiquidity or
failure
of one institution, and its resulting inability to meet its obligations
when
due, will lead to the illiquidity or failure of other institutions.”
The
prospect of systemic risk becomes commonplace when lenders are also
borrowers
who depend on the return of the funds they lent to pay for the sums
they
borrowed. Risk of illiquidity, not any drop in demand for goods or
loans, is
the improvised explosive device (IED) of financial terrorism that puts
in
harm’s way unsuspecting investors running a relay race in the debt
securitization thread mill.
<>Whether or when a
bubble will burst depends on the central
bank’s ability to extend the bubble’s elasticity, which is not
unlimited,
albeit flexible through inventive redefinitions of theoretical
relationships
and the cause-effect paradigm. To support the market, a central bank
needs
increasingly to intervene, which in turn destroys the market. As
is already apparent, the Federal Reserve
is increasingly reduced to an irrelevant role of rationalizing the
virtual
finance economy rather than directing it.
It has adopted the role of a cleanup crew rather than the guardian of
public financial health. Ironically, a cure for a debt bubble can come
from a
blood-letting asset hyper inflation, euphemistically called “unlocking
value”.
In that scenario, the traditional strategy of holding cash gives no
protection
because real currency value can fall faster than nominal asset price
depreciation. The name for such a scenario is hyper inflation which has
brought
down many governments a socio-economic systems in history.
In a
financial bubble, the real economy may not be growing, but the monetary
value
of financial assets rises, and is defined as growth, not inflation. Thus we have robust “recoveries” that
continue to lose jobs with the value of money protected by high
unemployment
and stagnant income from wages. Or we
can have a recovery with low unemployment with rising nominal income
that is
accompanied by a decline in real aggregate income with wages falling
behind
inflation. In the finance sector, wealth is created by escalating
systemic
risk-taking, known as the “Greenspan put.” Inflation and
deflation have
become two sides of the same coin that alternate as monetary concerns
in a
matter of months, through a highly-manipulated global foreign exchange
market
that tends to destabilize real economies via a multitude of conduits
such as
wealth effects, balance sheet effects, recurring alternates of credit
excesses
and crunches and liquidity booms and busts.
Central Banks Never Allow Deflation to Correct
Past Inflation
Central
banks seldom adjust their monetary policies to arrest asset bubbles and
related
imbalances and instabilities. The days of the central banker being the
spoiler
who takes away the punch bowl when the party gets going are long gone. Central bankers now bring stronger drinks
when the party slows. While central
banks still clings to the mandatory task of fighting inflation, they
never try
to reverse inflation by allowing deflation. Thus any battle lost
against
insipid inflation is a battle lost forever, with no prospect of ever
regaining
lost ground. Thus among market participants, bulls enjoy the advantage
of
having the wind of inflation behind them even in a continuous bear
market.
Inflation Targeting Becomes Labor Targeting
In the US, the
Fed has served notice that it
is prepared to move toward inflation targeting to prevent deflation, as
suggested by then board member Ben Bernanke, now Fed Chairman. Prices
of asset
can only go up but never allowed to fall, even to adjust previous
irrational
exuberance. Trapped by their own doctrinaire fixation, central banks
will continue to provide excess
liquidity to support asset price bubbles, and to mask the
destructiveness of
burst bubbles by unleashing new bubbles with more liquidity,
euphemistically
known as recoveries. At the same time, central banks will vehemently
fight
inflation as measured by rising wages. Thus central banking operates
with a
severe institutional bias against labor.
Market Volatility a Necessary Windows for
Financial Profit
In fact,
market volatility, another term for shot-term instability, in the
financial
sector of the economy has become a major source of profit for financial
institutions. Long-term investors are
endangered species in the financial world; most market participants
have become
leveraged traders for short-term profit, even pension funds and
university
endowment funds. The only factor of production that maintains any
semblance of
stability is wages.
The recurring
financial crises around the world shared
similar characteristics. Each crisis was largely unanticipated by
market
analysts and central bank economists, with the forward markets
providing no
indication of the impending upheaval. Going into each crisis,
complacent
traders took on highly leveraged long positions in currencies, bonds,
or spread
products that soon came under heavy speculative counterattack. In
each case, traders adopted trading models
constructed from historical paradigms to guide their trading
strategies. When a
decisive majority of traders followed similar trading strategies, the
market
would overshoot from technical pressure and conventional wisdom became
disconnected with reality. But once a crisis hit and conventional
wisdom was
discredited by facts, traders rushed to liquidate their highly
leveraged
positions en mass, hoping for timely exit before the crowd. In each
instance,
the rush to unwind highly-leveraged positions accentuated the magnitude
of the
currency or fixed-income crises.
Exchange Rates and
Purchasing Power Parity
Theoretically,
exchange rates adjust to achieve purchasing
power parity (PPP) between two currencies. PPP is achieved when a unit
of
domestic currency can purchase the same quantity of goods in another
economy
when converted to foreign currency at the prevailing exchange rate, to
conform
to the law of one price. If PPP holds, then identical baskets of goods
should
sell for the same price in each economy after exchange rate conversion.
If they
do not, then opportunities for “risk-free profits” will exist through
arbitrage
in foreign exchange markets that translates into massive flows of funds
across
national borders. Eventually, price arbitrage will set a market
exchange rate
or the prices of goods in the two economies will change so that PPP
between the
two currencies is reestablished. With deregulated global capital
markets,
prices of assets also adjust towards convergence of PPP between two
currencies
to cause market crashes.
Profiting from Market
Overshoots
In adjusting, the
market tends to overshoot up or down like
the swing of a pendulum until equilibrium sets in. But if the
overshoot is boosted each time by
speculative forces, then the swings of the pendulum will never reach
equilibrium. The dollar exchange rate overshoots of 1985 and 1995,
similar to
the 1994 global bear market in bonds, proved to be transitory
events. But while the dollar crisis episodes
represented dramatic overshoots at major turning points in the dollar’s
long-term trend of decline, the 1994 global bond market sell-off in
hind sight
seemed to be simply an interruption of a long-term rally in global
bonds,
although substantial losses were incurred during the sell-off.
This was because the Fed used a bigger bubble
to cushion the collapsing bond bubble, keeping interest rates low,
causing nominal
bond prices to rise, while in fact real value of bond might have
declined.
The Lessons of 1994
It is instructive to
analyze the situation in 1994 because
the data and dynamics are by now indisputable. Going into 1994, many
highly-leveraged fund managers had taken on huge long-duration
positions in
several key markets after riding the 1993 global bull market in bonds
created
by historically low interest rates, and thought that additional hefty
returns
could be achieved in 1994 by maintaining those highly-leveraged long
positions.
But they evidently ignored the fact that leading indicators of global
economic
activity were already turning up strongly from the long period of
monetary ease
accompanied by currency devaluation, making those long positions
extremely
vulnerable if there should be a shift in monetary policy towards
tightness,
meaning rising interest rates.
The Federal
Reserve’s rate hike from its low of 1% that
began on June 30 1994 that
eventually reached the current 5.25% on June 29, 2006 was the catalyst
for traders to unwind their
highly-leveraged long positions, triggering a major sell-off in bond
markets
around the globe. Global bond yields rose by 200-300 basis points, or
2-3
percentage points, on average over the first three quarters of 1994,
causing a
collapse in bond prices. By the fourth quarter of 1994, bond yields
managed to
stabilize and then begin to fall steadily in 1995, causing a bond price
rebound. By late 1995, bond yields had returned to their pre-crisis
levels.
This pattern of
collapse followed by stabilization and then
recovery through stealth inflation was not too dissimilar from the
pattern of
the dollar’s collapse in early 1995. In both crises, the collapse stage
took
place over a 3-6-month period, followed by a period of stabilization
that
lasted about three months and a recovery period that took place over a
3-12-month period.
But were these real
recoveries, or were they merely the
stabilization of uneven currency devaluation?
Could it be that the dollar never did recover, but other currencies
finally caught up with the dollar’s collapse? Dollars interest rates
were not
rising at a pace demanded by its fall in real purchasing power.
More Lessons in 1998
The 1998 credit
spread crisis shares a number of similar
features with the 1994 bond market crisis. As in the 1994 crisis, fund
managers
in 1998 once again took on aggressive highly-leveraged long positions,
this
time in spread products, evidently believing that credit spreads would
continue
to narrow. Unfortunately, Russia’s
decision on August 26 1998
to engineer a controlled default on its debt obligations led to a
complete
re-assessment of credit risk by global investors. The herd-like rush to
exit
caused the collapse of the hedge fund LTCM.
Fear that default
risk might increase and spread worldwide
led to a mad scramble for liquidity. Quality spreads in the US
corporate bond market widened dramatically and stood at recession
levels.
Indeed, the yield spread between Baa corporate bonds and US Treasuries
widened
to levels not seen since the 1990-91 recession. US
corporations became less willing to borrow and therefore curtailed
investment-spending, which clearly dampened US
growth in subsequent years. High-yield spreads are tied to fundamentals
such as
expected future default rates. But spreads are also related to market
liquidity
in ways that are not yet well understood even by the most seasoned
professionals.
Liquidity Can
Disappear Quickly
Liquidity, a
fundamental concept relating to the quantity of
money in monetary policy, can also be defined in the market as the
ability to
buy or sell large quantities of assets quickly and at low discount and
cost.
Normally liquid assets can become illiquid in a market meltdown. The
vast
majority of equilibrium asset pricing models do not consider the effect
of trading
and thus ignore the time and cost of transforming financial assets into
cash or
vice versa, particularly in times of distress or exuberance, rational
or
irrational. Recent financial crises, however, suggest that, at times,
market
conditions can become suddenly severe and liquidity can decline or even
disappear extremely quickly, even overnight or even in the middle of a
trading
day. Such liquidity shocks are a
potential channel through which asset prices are influenced, or
distorted by
liquidity.
The Decoupling of
Bonds from Stocks
In 1994, the bond
market was caught on the wrong side of
economic fundamentals and yanked down with the shifting tide of higher
rates at
the Fed. But stocks skated through relatively unscathed, because credit
was
still available and investors recognized the bond market needed an
adjustment
that more accurately reflected the central bank’s new thinking.
A bond fund’s
“duration” measures the theoretical impact
that one percentage point rise in interest rates would have on the net
asset
value of a fund. A bond fund with five-year “duration” could be
expected to
drop by 5% in value if interest rates rose by one percentage point.
Conversely,
a one percentage point drop in rates would cause a fund with five-year
duration
to increase by 5% in value.
To figure total
return, changes to net asset value (NAV)
should be added or subtracted from the income generated by the fund. So
a bond
portfolio with a 3% yield whose NAV drops 5% would suffer a loss of 2%
on a
total return basis over a 12-month period.
Long-term bond funds
often have effective durations of at
least seven years. In that case, a rise in long-term interest rates of
2
percentage points over the next 12 months would cause at least a 14%
drop in
value. With yields on long-term Treasury bonds at 5%, such an increase
would
translate into a loss of 9% or more for fund shareholders - similar to
when the
Fed tightened monetary policy in 1994.
To protect against
that possibility, investors keep
fixed-income money in short-term corporate bonds, typically with
durations of
six months or less. With yields of long bonds below 5%, it would take a
9
percentage point boost in short-term interest rates just to push the
total
return on such funds into the red over a one-year period. In the
current
environment of massive over-capacity and debt, the chances of that
happening
are about zero. That is why long bonds will rise as surely as
tomorrow’s sun.
The Lessons of 2003
In July 2003,
Federal Reserve officials engaged in damage
control after Greenspan spooked the bond market in congressional
testimony by
suggesting that FFR at 1% might have
fallen as low as they will go. Greenspan further disappointed investors
by
noting that the Fed was unlikely to engage in “unconventional” market
activities,
such as buying long-term government bonds to drive down long-term rates
which
had stayed inverted for extended periods.
The policy of using
interest rate cuts to pump up demand has
been tested to destruction since 1994. But all policies carry costs.
The costs
in this case included most obviously the dangers both of pushing down
long-term
interest rates as well as short-term to a level that may be
unsustainable, and
subsequently re-igniting inflationary pressures. In other words, the
Federal
Reserve was creating a bond bubble similar to the equity bubble, and
then
protecting the equity bubble by creating conditions where that bond
bubble
would be popped. But investors that anticipated this scenario were
fooled.
Long-term rates stayed low because massive capital in-flow came from
foreign
central banks operating under dollar hegemony. Bonds rose in 1994
further and
faster than at any stage in the previous 4 decades and collapsed in
1996 and
again in 2003.
Once market
participants think the market is turning against
bonds through a rise in interest rates, they are likely to stampede out
of
bonds, creating a bond crash similar to the equity crash. Traders hedge
their
risk exposure in bonds with compensating position in interest rate
futures by
adopting immunization strategies by constant rebalancing price risk
with coupon
reinvestment risk which changes in opposite directions. In the 1950s
the bond
market was considered a safe, conservative investment. At that time a
buy-and-hold strategy was sufficient. However, since the 1960s,
inflation has
increased, and interest rates have become more volatile. Thus, with
more
volatile interest rates, there exists a greater profit potential with
bonds.
Also, the Macaulay duration, named after introducer of the concept,
being the
weighted average maturity of a bond where the weights are the relative
discounted cash flows in each period, came into use in the 1970s.
Under conditions of
a liquidity boom, rising rates lowers
bond prices as well as equity prices. That combination is explosive
enough, but
adding to it the impotence of rising interest rates to halt the
declining value
of the dollar, we have a mixture of deadly financial dynamite that can
be
detonated by seemingly unrelated minor developments at unexpected times.
Psychological Effect
of a Bond Crash
The psychosocial
effect of a bond crash on market sentiment
is highly damaging. Market participants and investors have been
conditioned to
think that lower return on bonds are justified by their being less
risky than
equities. On a 30-year or longer basis, this is a correct view, but not
on a
three or five-year term. Under current market conditions, there exists
at least
as large a possibility of 10-year bonds falling by 25% over the any 18
months
as there is of shares falling by the same amount. Yet investors in
bonds do not
have that same awareness of risk as equity investors, so the
consequences could
be serious. A typical portfolio with
one-third in bonds will not escape losses in a bear market.
Total Return Swaps
Total return swaps
(TRS) can make short-term dollar loans
(liabilities) appear as portfolio investments. Also, the requirement to
meet
margin or collateral calls on derivatives may generate sudden, large
foreign
exchange flows that would not be indicated by the amount of foreign
debt and
securities in a nation's balance of payments accounts. As a result, the
balance
of payments accounts no longer serve as well to assess country risk.
Even for
the dollar, which is protected by dollar hegemony in which the US
can print more dollars at will, the long-term consequences of currency
devaluation will cause structural damage to both the economy and
investors. In
the event of currency devaluation or a sharp downturn in securities
prices,
derivatives such as foreign exchange forwards and swaps and TRS
functioned to
quicken the pace and deepen the impact of the crisis.
Derivatives
transactions with emerging market financial institutions
generally
involve strict collateral or margin requirements. Asian firms swapping
the TRS
on a local security against LIBOR (London Inter-bank Offer Rate) post
US
dollars or Treasury securities as collateral; the rate of
collateralization is
estimated at around 20 percent of the national principal of the swap.
If the
market value of the swap position were to decline, then East Asian
firms would
have to add to their collateral in order to bring it up required
maintenance
level. Thus a sharp fall in the price of the underlying security, such
as would
occur at the beginning of a currency devaluation or broader financial
crisis,
would require Asian firms to immediately add dollar assets to their
collateral
in proportion to the loss in the present value of their swap position.
This
would trigger an immediate outflow of foreign currency reserves as
local
currency and other assets were exchanged into dollars in order to meet
their
collateral requirements. This would not only quicken the pace of the
crisis, it
would also deepen the impact of the crisis by putting further downward
pressure
on the exchange rate and asset prices thus increasing the losses to the
financial sector.
The Mergers and
Acquisition Time Bomb
In 2006, the dollar
volume for merger and acquisitions deals
was $4 trillion, which was one third of US GDP.
What are mergers?
Mergers between corporations in theory create value
by
improving efficiency and synergy in an overcapacity economy. This
is
generally achieved by laying off redundant workers and executives to
create a
leaner merged company and by selling off non-core subsidiaries
that could
be run more profitably by others. Generally, mergers shrink
production
and business activities to improve profit margin and reduce
competition. In
other words, mergers squeeze financial value from downsizing the
economy.
What are
acquisitions? Acquisitions of Public companies by private
equity firms
are attempts to create value by taking public companies private on the
theory
that public companies are inherently inefficient because of regulations
on
corporate governance, such as the Sarbine-Oxley Act. By taking public
companies
private, the new private owner can restructure the company with greater
flexibility out of the public eye with less disclosure and to resell
the
restructured company for high profit within a relatively short time,
usually to
a public corporate buyer or through an IPO. The irony is that private
equity
firms are now lining up to sell equity to the public, which is the
equivalence
of the anti-prostitution Church running a Cat House.
These trends are by
definition cyclical, depending of a fragile
combination of
abundant cheap money and low price of the target companies and an
enabling tax
structure. For example, one of causes of the 1987 crash, aside from the
exchange rate effects of the Plaza and Louvre Accords, was a threat by
the US
House of Representatives Ways and Means Committee to eliminate the tax
deduction for interest expenses incurred in leveraged buyouts. Still
another
cause was the 1986 US Tax Act, which while sharply lowering marginal
tax rates,
nevertheless raised the capital gains tax to 28% from 20% and left
capital
gains without the protection against inflated gains that indexing would
have
provided. This caused investors to sell equities to avoid negative net
after-tax returns and contributed significantly to the 1987 crash.
There were
other factors, such as the effect of portfolio insurance on the futures
market,
etc. At present, the IRS allows carry fees earned by private equity
firms to be
taxed at 15% capital gain rate rather than the 35% orfdinary income tax
rate. A
change in that ruling can do havoc to the private equity sector,
The Wall Street
Journal ran a report by William M. Bulkeley on June 7,
2007
that the IRS shut a corporate-tax loophole two days after IBM used it
on March
29 to avoid $1.6 billion in US taxes by structuring a $12.5 billion
share
buyback through a new subsidiary in the Netherlands. The
IRS calls
the IBM maneuver a "Triangular Reorganization" in which the
foreign unit spent $1 billion in cash and $11.5 billion in borrowed
funds to
buy 188.8 million shares, or 8% of outstanding, from a group of
investment
banks what had borrowed the shares from institutional investors. The
investment
banks will buy share in the open market for returning the borrowed
shared over
the next nine months and IBM will make whole any losses to the
investment banks
if IBM share prices should rise. IBM intends to repay the loans
with
earnings from its foreign subsidiaries with tax rates averaging 22%,
substantially below the average US rate of 40%, saving $1.6
billion. The
contradiction, aside from tax avoidance with no business purpose, is
that the
transaction gave IBM a reduced incentive to see its share rise in the
open
market until the $11.5 billion loans are repaid.
The PPI/CPI Spread
Since 2003, the
producer price index (PPI) has risen by
16.4%, while the consumer price index (CPI) is only up 12.5%. This is
caused by
globalized trade through cross-border wage arbitrage keeping consumer
prices
down. CPI is heavily weighted toward import prices while PPI is
weighted toward
export prices. Import prices fall while export prices rise when the
dollar
rises against foreign currencies.
Even though exchange
rate is only a part of the reasons for the US trade deficit, Congress
has fixated on the idea of forcing China to revalue its currency upward
against the dollar. But a falling dollar causes China's central bank to
demand compensatory higher dollar interest rates for the US sovereign
debt it buys, which in turn slows the US economy.
A higher short-term
rate is important in its inflationary effect on CPI because it drives
the rates for much of consumer credit, such as credit-card loans and
auto loans, as well as adjustable home mortgages. The long 10-year bond
rate drives fixed mortgage rates only at the time the mortgage is
taken, but rising long-term rates will depress the price of outstanding
long bonds to compensate for the gap in yields.
A falling dollar
will artificially lift overseas profits of US transnational
corporations and in turn lift equity prices while the US domestic
economy stagnates or declines.
Opening Foreign
Financial Markets to Rescue the US Trade Deficit
Among the objections
against globalization: including income
inequality, workers’ rights abuse and the environment abuse, the most
serious
has been the devastating recurring destruction brought on by
currency-induced
financial crises in developing countries. In the past decade,
globalization has
also depressed wages in the advanced economies.
But now the destructiveness of financial globalization is beginning to
be undeniable. Even pro-globalized trade economists now are forced to
acknowledge cross border capital flows as the Fifth Horseman of
Apocalypse of
financial globalization through no-holds-barred deregulation and
liberalization
in structured finance that leaves large segment of the world’s
population in
all countries in financial ruins.
The comparative advantage of “free trade” has
long been neutralized by a dysfunctional international finance
architecture
that devastates the poor and weak in all economies, rich or poor. Amid
this
growing resistance, the US
is trying to ply open financial markets faster everywhere, particularly
China.
Central Banks Distort
Domestic Prices
In today’s
globalized financial markets, the central bank in
every nation distorts all prices in the local economy to prevent
economic
adaptation to changing world prices in key commodities, such as oil.
Domestic
interest rates are forced to rise during a recession to prevent capital
flight.
This is true regardless if the currency is free-floating or pegged to
the
dollar. The only difference is that the penalties manifest themselves
in
different forms, via asset depreciation for floating currencies and via
a drain
in foreign reserves in pegged currencies. As noted earlier, dollar
hegemony
uses currency crisis as the widely-deployed improvised explosive devise
(IED)
in finance terrorism against domestic development in all countries rich
and
poor.
Ironically, while
the advance economies are plague with
overcapacity from stagnation and disparity of income, there is rising
evidence
that low-wage production in East and South Asia, which
in the past decade has been the main factor in containing global
inflation, is
going through a sea change to build pressure for global
inflation. While unemployment is still serious all over Asia,
including booming economies such as China
and India,
existing plants in the export sectors of these countries are running
near full
capacity. This is because foreign investment goes only into projects
that yield
extraordinary return on foreign investment from low wages in the export
sector
while unemployment continues to rise in the domestic sectors.
Social and political
pressures in reaction to income
disparity are giving labor everywhere a stronger voice in demanding
more equal
distribution of the benefits of globalized trade, in the form of living
wages
and more liberal benefits and protection of worker rights. Thus while
both
China and India are still burdened with oversupply of human resources
with a
glut of underemployment or high unemployment, plant capacity in their
export
sectors can grow only at higher costs to meet consumer demand in their
export
markets for low-cost goods. This is because the excess labor is located
in the
rural interior where there are no plants and where the cost of building
new
plants and the transportation network to serve the export sector are
economically not viable. And the plants located along the coastal
regions are
experiencing a labor shortage because more migrant workers cannot be
accommodated for lack of low-cost housing.
But higher costs in China
will result in higher prices for Chinese exports and reduced US
demand for goods until US
wages rise, which is registered as inflation. As a result, central
banks of the
world are increasingly anxious about structural inflation, forcing them
to
tighten monetary policy by raising interest rates. The Goldilock era of
a happy
combination of high growth, low inflation and low interest rates may be
coming
to an end. Fed Chairman Ben Bernanke told a bankers conference in South
Africa on June 5 that
rising wages and
environmental costs in China
would have an upward effect on US
inflation. The IMF has calculated that low-wage imports from China
had reduced US
inflation by one percentage point. Many economic projections expect
global
growth will no longer contain inflation. Rather, going forward, further
global
growth will translate into inflationary pressures.
With cost-pushed
inflation bringing higher interest rates in
a cycle of slowing economy and weaker earnings caused by a housing
bust, rising
wages that still fail to keep up with real inflation from currency
devaluation,
dwindling consumer demand from income disparity, with trade friction
threatening to turn into protectionist measures, cheap money can
evaporate
quickly to put a sudden stop to the recent merger and acquisition
frenzy by
private equity firms, and turn completed deals into bankruptcy
candidates.
While each of these developments may not by itself be serious enough to
bring
the economy to a halt, a confluence of all such interrelation
developments can
produce a whirlpool effect that sucks everything down a black hole of
vanishing
virtual money.
Income is All
The fountainhead of
this financial whirlpool is located in
the conundrum that rising interest rates are impotent in reversing the
decline
of the purchasing power of the dollar. What is needed is a redefinition
of
economic growth to be measured by rising purchasing power of wages
rather than
by nominal GDP increases. And that path is through closing the
disparity of
income and wealth in every economy, rich and poor, among people and
between
economies.
The timeless adage in economics that income is all holds even more
true today.
|