|
Greenspan Characterized Regulatory Arbitrage as
Desirable
By
Henry C.K. Liu
This article appeared in AToL on June 24, 2009 as
False profits and prophecies and
on the
website of New Deal 2.0,
a project of
the Franklin and Eleanor Roosevelt Institute as
Of Profits and Prophecy: Alan Greenspan’s
Errors in Judgment
In my June 18, 2009 AToL article: Tip-toe
regulatory reform, I referred to George
Soros, the speculator who broke the Bank of England over its defense of
the pound sterling, as having said in the Financial Times that a requirement for lenders selling
securitized loans as securities to retain 5 per cent exposure "is more symbolic
than substantive". This is because many institutions were playing
the
game of regulatory arbitrage, the
practice of taking advantage of a regulatory difference between two or
more markets.
The issue of regulatory arbitrage was discussed in my recent
article (
May 25, 2009) on my website: Mark-to-Market
vs Mark-to-Model, an abridged version of
which also appeared on the website of New Deal 2.0, a project of
the Franklin and Eleanor Roosevelt Institute.
AIG Financial Products (AIGFP), based in London
where the regulatory regime was less restrictive, took advantage of AIG
statue
categorization as an insurance company and therefore not subject to the
same
burdensome rules on capital reserves as banks. AIG would not need to
set aside
anything but a tiny sliver of capital if it would insure the
super-senior risk
tranches of CDOs in its holdings. Nor was the insurer likely to face
hard
questions from its own regulators because AIGFS had largely fallen
through the
interagency cracks of oversight. It was regulated by the US Office for
Thrift
Supervision, whose staff had inadequate expertise in the field of
cutting-edge
structured finance products.
AIGFP insured bank-held super-senior risk CDOs in the broad
CDS market. AIG would earn a relatively trifle fee for providing this
coverage
– just 0.02 cents for each dollar insured per year. For the buyer of
such
insurance, the cost is insignificant for the critical benefit,
particularly in
the financial advantage associated with a good credit rating, which the
buyer
receives not because the instruments are “safe” but only that the risk
was
insured by AIGFP. For AIG, with 0.02 cents multiplied a few hundred
billion
times, it adds up to an appreciable income stream, particularly if no
reserves
are required to cover the supposedly non-existent risk. Regulators were
told by
the banks that a way had been found to remove all credit risk from
their CDO
deals.
As an example, an investor buys a CDS contract from a
triple-A-rated
Bank to insure against the eventuality of a counterparty defaulting, by
making regular insurance
payments to the bank for the protection. If the counterparty defaults
on its commitment anytime during the duration of the contract by
missing an agreed interest payment or failed to repay the principle at
maturity, the investor will
be assured to receive a one-off payment of the insured amount from the
bank whose credit rating is triple-A and the CDS contract is
terminated. If the investor actually holds the debt from the
counterparty, the CDS contract works as a hedge against counterparty
default.. But investors can also buy CDS contracts
on debts they do not hold, but as a speculative play, to bet against
the
solvency of one side of the any counterpary relationship in a gamble to
make money if it fails, or to
hedge investments in other parties whose fortunes are expected to be
similar to those of target party.
If a counterparty defaults, one of two things can
happen:
1) the insured investor delivers a defaulted asset
to the insurer Bank
for a payment at par value. This is known as physical settlement,
or
2) the insuring Bank pays the investor the difference
between the par
value
and the market price of a specified debt obligation after recovery
to cover the loss. This is known as cash settlement.
The spread of a CDS is the annual amount the protection buyer
must pay the protection seller over the length of the contract,
expressed as a percentage of the notional value. For example, if the
CDS spread of counterparty risk is 100 basis points (1%), then an
investor buying $100 million
worth of protection from the insuring Bank must pay the bank $1 million
per year.
These payments continue until either the CDS contract expires or the
target counterparty defaults, at which point the insuring bank pays the
insured of outstanding value owed by of the counterparty.
All things being equal, at any given time, if the
maturity of two
credit default swaps is the same, then the CDS associated with a
particular counterparty with a higher CDS spread is
considered more
likely
to default by the market, since a higher fee is being charged to
protect against this happening. However, factors such as liquidity and
estimated loss given default can impact the comparison. When spread
skyrocket during a market seizure, insurers can fail because they
are
not required to adjust regular income statements to show balance
sheet
volatility. This was what happened to AIG which provided no reserves
for its CDS contracts.
Systemic Risk and Credit Rating
There were two dimensions to the cause of the current
credit crisis. The first was that unit risk was not eliminated, merely
transferred to a larger pool to make it invisible statistically. The
second,
and more ominous, was that regulatory risks were defined by credit
ratings, and
the two fed on each other inversely. As credit rating rose, risk
exposure fell
to create an under-pricing of risk. But as risk exposure rose, credit
rating
fell to exacerbate further rise of risk exposure in a chain reaction
that
detonated a debt explosion of atomic dimension.
The Office of the Comptroller of the Currency and the Federal
Reserve jointly allowed banks with credit default swaps (CDS) insurance
to keep super-senior
risk
assets on their books without adding capital because the risk was
insured.
Normally, if the banks held the super-senior risk on their books, they
would
need to post capital at 8% of the liability. But capital could be
reduced to one-fifth the
normal
amount (20% of 8%, meaning $160 for every $10,000 of risk on the books)
if
banks could prove to the regulators that the risk of default on the
super-senior portion of the deals was truly negligible, and if the
securities
being issued via a collateral debt obligation (CDO) structure carried a
Triple-A credit rating from a “nationally recognized credit rating
agency”,
such as Standard and Poor’s rating on AIG.
With CDS insurance, banks then could cut the normal $800
million capital for every $10 billion of corporate loans on their books
to just
$160 million, meaning banks with CDS insurance can loan up to five
times more
on the same capital. The CDS-insured CDO deals could then bypass
international
banking rules on capital. To correct
this bypass is a key reason why the government wanted to conduct stress
tests
on banks in 2009 to see if banks need to raise new capital in a
Downward Loss
Given Default.
CDS contracts are generally subject to mark-to-market
accounting that introduces regular periodic income statements to show
balance
sheet volatility that would not be present in a regulated insurance
contract.
Further, the buyer of a CDS does not even need to own the underlying
security
or other form of credit exposure. In fact, the buyer does not even have
to
suffer an actual loss from the default event, only a virtual loss would
suffice
for collection of the insured notional amount. So, at 0.02 cents to a
dollar (1
to 10,000 odd), speculators could place bets to collect astronomical
payouts in
billions with affordable losses. A $10, 000 bet on a CDS default could
stand to
win $100,000,000 within a year. That was exactly what many hedge funds
did
because they could recoup all their lost bets even if they only won
once in
10,000 years. As it
turns out, many only had to wait a a couple
of years before winning a huge windfall. But until AIG was bailed out
by the Fed, these hedge funds were not sure they could collect their
winnings.
Alan Greenspan, the former chairman of the
Federal Reserve under whose
watch much regulatory arbitrage took place, was not unaware of the problem
of regulatory arbitrage, but
he chose to permit it as he viewed it as "desirable".
In The
Role of Capital in Optimal Banking Supervision and Regulation
(FRBNY ECONOMIC POLICY REVIEW / OCTOBER 1998
page 163)
Greenspan wrote :
"It is clear that our major banks have become quite efficient at
engaging in such desirable forms of regulatory capital arbitrage,
through securitization and other devices."
Greenspan wrote that "a reasonable principle for setting regulatory
soundness
standards is to act much as the market would if there were no safety
net and all market participants were fully informed. For example,
requiring all of our regulated financial institutions to maintain
insolvency probabilities that are
equivalent to a triple-A rating standard would be demonstrably too
stringent because there are very few such entities among unregulated
financial institutions not subject to the safety net."
He went on: "We have no choice but to continue to plan for a successor
to the simple
risk-weighting approach to capital requirements embodied within the
current regulatory standard. While it is unclear at present exactly
what that successor might be, it seems clear that adding more and more
layers of arbitrary regulation would be counterproductive. We should,
rather, look for ways to harness market tools and market-like
incentives whenever possible, by using banks’ own policies, behaviors,
and technologies in improving the supervisory process."
And he went further: "Finally, we should always remind ourselves that
supervision and
regulation are neither infallible nor likely to prove sufficient to
meet all our intended goals. Put another way, the Basle
standard and
the bank examination process, even if structured in optimal fashion,
are a second line of support for bank soundness. Supervision and
regulation can never be a substitute for a bank’s own internal scrutiny
of its counterparties and for the market’s scrutiny of the
bank. Therefore, we should not, for example, abandon efforts to
contain the scope of the safety net or to press for increases in the
quantity and quality of financial disclosures by regulated
institutions."
In other words, Greenspan looked to self regulation as the first line
of defense and increased disclosure as the appropriate path, not
supervision and regulation.
Greenspan concluded: "If we follow these basic prescriptions, I suspect
that history will
look favorably on our attempts at crafting regulatory policy."
Unfortunately, Greenspan was
unjustifiably complacent about how history would judge
him and his views on
regulation.
June 22, 2009
|
|
|
|