|
Paulson
and China
By
Henry
C.K. Liu
This article
appeared in AToL on December 13, 2006
With
some
27 anti-China trade bills pending in various stages of legislative
process
and prospects of passage in Congress as background, and a just released
critical report on Chinese trade practices by the US Trade
Representative, US Treasury
Secretary Henry M. Paulson Jr., an expert on China with over 70
business trips
there as a private banker, will go to China with six other Cabinet
members and
the chairman of the Federal Reserve, Ben Bernanke, to discuss US-China
trade
relations. The venue is the first meeting of a newly created
semi-annual “strategic
economic dialogue” to be held in Beijing
on December 13-15. In addition to Paulson and Bernanke, the other top US
officials making the trip are Commerce Secretary Carlos Gutierrez, US
Trade
Representative Susan Schwab, Labor Secretary Elaine Chao, Heath and
Human
Services Secretary Mike Leavitt, Energy Secretary Sam Bodman and
Stephen
Johnson, head of the Environmental Protection Agency.
A fact
sheet issued by the Department of the Treasury on September 20, 2006 states:
President
George W. Bush and President Hu Jintao have agreed to create a
Strategic
Economic Dialogue between the United
States
and China.
Reflecting the growing relationship between the US
and Chinese economies, this dialogue will occur at the highest official
levels
and is the first of its kind. Further, it will provide an
overarching
framework for ongoing productive bilateral economic dialogues and
future
economic relations. It will examine long-term strategic issues,
as well
as provide coordination among the specialized continuing
dialogues. The
Strategic Economic Dialogue will also be a forum for discussing ways
the United States
and China
can work together to address economic challenges and opportunities as
responsible stakeholders in the international economic system.
The
essential goal of this dialogue is to ensure that the
benefits of our growing economic relationship with China
are fairly shared by citizens of both countries.
The
Strategic Economic Dialogue will convene semi-annually
in the United States
and China,
with
the first meeting occurring before the end of 2006. Each of the
two
Presidents will strongly support and take an active role in the
strategic
economic dialogue.
President
Bush has designated Secretary of the Treasury
Henry M. Paulson to lead the US
side of the dialogue. National Economic Adviser Al Hubbard and other
members of
the President’s Cabinet will join Secretary Paulson. Additional U.S.
agencies will include Commerce, U.S.
Trade Representative, State, Health and Human Services, the
Environmental
Protection Agency, Energy and others. Deborah Lehr [who has
resigned
after only three weeks] will serve as Special Envoy to the Strategic
Economic
Dialogue to ensure it receives the attention and continuity necessary
to
produce meaningful results.
President
Hu has designated Vice Premier Wu Yi to lead the
Chinese side of the dialogue. In that role, she has been given
full
decision-making authority across all aspects of the Chinese
economy. To
demonstrate the importance of the Dialogue, the Chinese government has
created
its largest and the highest ranking inter-ministerial working group
which Vice
Premier Wu Yi will chair, supported by Foreign Minister Li Zhaoxing,
Finance
Minister Jin Renqing, and Deputy Secretary General of the State Council
Xu
Shaoshi, as well as the Ministries of Commerce, Agriculture, Health,
and
Information Industries, the various financial regulators, the National
Development and Reform Commission, the People's Bank of China and
others.
The
Strategic Economic Dialogue will help to ensure leaders
of the two countries can address critical economic challenges facing
their
economies, have a forum for discussing cross-cutting issues, and can
make the
most productive use of the existing bilateral commissions and
dialogues. Likely
themes of the discussions will include: building innovative societies,
seizing
the opportunities of global economic integration to assure sustained
growth,
and the economics of energy and conservation. The United
States will also support China
in China's
goal
of building a consumer-driven economy rooted in open markets. The
intent
of this dialogue is to discuss long-term strategic challenges, rather
than
seeking immediate solutions to the issues of the day.
The
discussion of long-term structural issues in the
Strategic Economic Dialogue will provide a stronger foundation for
pursuing
concrete results through existing bilateral economic dialogues and
ensuring
citizens of both countries benefit fairly from the growing bilateral
economic
relationship. The new strategic dialogue will provide support and
guidance for these existing bilateral economic forums, which will
remain
essential to managing specialized aspects of the interdependent
US-China
economic relationship. These high level discussions will enhance, not
diminish
these existing forums. Bilateral issues will continue to receive
full
attention, including pressing China
for floating exchange rates, greater intellectual property rights, and
increasing market access.
Existing
economic and related dialogues include:
The
Joint Commission on Commerce and Trade (JCCT) between
the US Department of Commerce, the U.S. Trade Representative, and the
Chinese
Vice Premier responsible for trade.
The
Joint Economic Committee between the U.S.
Department of the Treasury and the Chinese Ministry of Finance.
Joint
Commission on Science and Technology between the U.S.
Director of the Office of Science and Technology Policy and the Chinese
Ministry of Science and Technology.
The
Economic Development and Reform Dialogue between the U.S.
Department of State and China's
National Development and Reform Commission.
The
Energy Policy Dialogue between the U.S.
Department of Energy and China's
National Development and Reform Commission.
The
Global Issues Forum led by the U.S. Department of State
and China's
Ministry of Foreign Affairs.
The
Healthcare Forum between the U.S.
Department of Health and Human Services and the Chinese Ministry of
Health.
The
Asia-Pacific Partnership on Clean Development and
Climate, which brings together China, the United States, Australia,
India,
Japan, and Korea. (End)
Intense
pressure is on the new Secretary to produce tangible
results of Chinese acquiescence to rising US
trade complaints or face a wave of protectionist measures in the new
Congress
next year that could reverse long-standing US
preference for free trade. Paulson conferred last week with US business
leaders all of whom urged him to use the considerable power of his
office to bring
about accelerated changes in China’s trade policies and practices,
particularly
in opening and deregulating Chinese markets, abandoning the alleged
manipulation
of currency levels to spur exports, or at least to manipulate it
upwards against
the dollar to reduce its enormous and still rising trade surplus with
the US. Also on
the Secretary’s agenda is a mission to convince Chinese authorities of
the need
to suspend illegal subsidies to such industries as steel and auto
parts, crack
down on piracy of computer and entertainment software, pharmaceuticals,
and other
intellectual property issues to avoid US retaliatory measures.
To
prepare for the high-level trip on December 13, Treasury
aides have been conferring with their Chinese counterparts to lay the
groundwork for an image of diplomatic progress if not immediate
substantive resolutions.
Both sides on the discussion table cautioned the public not to expect
unrealistic
breakthroughs on difficult key issues, in part because Chinese domestic
politics is
sensitive to US
infringement on Chinese national sovereignty and US domestic politics
is trigger
happy with rash reactions to disappointment from unrealistic
expectations on
intractable trade issues with China.
There
is much that is dysfunctional and unsustainable in
US-China economic relations. The unhappy situation is the natural
result of
inequitable terms of trade that have evolved over two decades,
beginning with
China’s economic opening to the outside world in Deng Xiaoping’s reform
policy
introduced in 1978. Since the end of WWII, the US
has conducted US foreign economic and trade policies on the basis that
trade
with the US
is
a favor the rich US
economy grants to the poorer economies. The conditions that render such
attitude operative have changed as the US,
in an interdependent global economy, has become addicted to low price
imports
to fuel its loose monetary policy based on dollar hegemony. The US
economy now is dependent on foreign trade as much as, if not more than,
the
exporting economies. Victims of addiction are usually not in any
position to
dictate the terms of supply.
A Trade Deficit is
in the US National Interest
A case
can be made, although few in the US
are intellectually honest enough or politically courageous enough to
make it,
that a rising trade deficit is in the US
national interest, just as a strong dollar is in the US
national interest. Dollar hegemony, a term that describes the effect of
the dollar,
a fiat currency, assuming the unmerited role of the key reserve
currency for
international trade, enables the US
to use its capital account surplus to fund its trade deficit. For this
reason,
a balanced trade with the rest of the world would dry up the capital
account
surplus and create serious structural problem for the US
financial system that needs $3 billion of net capital inflow a day to
keep
afloat.
Many
in the US
fear a new threat to the sustainability of US
hegemony emerging in the form of excessive dependence on foreign
capital and
growing foreign debt. Former Treasury Secretary Lawrence Summers of the
Clinton
Administration observed that “there is something odd about the world’s
greatest
power being the world’s greatest debtor.”
Actually,
what is odd is US
foreign debt being denominated in dollars, a fiat currency that the US
and only the US
can print at will. The US
is the only nation in the world whose foreign debt is denominated in
its own
currency. In that sense, the US
has no real foreign debt as all its debts are sovereign debts payable
in
currency it can issue at will. The term foreign debt usually means debt
denominated in foreign currencies. Such debts require the backing of
adequate
foreign reserves because the debtor governments cannot print foreign
currencies
and are therefore subject to risks of default on foreign currency
loans.
Foreign debts for the US,
as they are denominated in dollars, are only sovereign debts held by
foreigners.
If the foreigners holding US
sovereign debt want to cash them in, the US
can print as much dollar as it needs to satisfy them. Therefore the US
does not face risks of default on its foreign debts. This is what makes
US
sovereign debts relatively safe investments, as sovereign debts are not
exposed
to default risk, only foreign exchange risk. The key behind the
intrinsic value
of the dollar is that dollars, and only dollars, are accepted by the US
government for payment of taxes and all other governmental receipts.
These
characteristics, laid out as the State Theory of Money, make the dollar
a
political instrument exempt from rules that govern financial
instruments.
A New Approach to China
Following
his first major speech that signaled a new US
economic approach to China, Paulson told the Financial Times on the eve
of his
first trip to China (September 22) as Treasury Secretary that his
message to
China was: “We want you to succeed.” Paulson said: “The United
States has a huge stake in a
prosperous,
stable China
–
a China
able
and willing to play its part as a global economic leader.” He said the US
and China
shared areas of economic interest, highlighting energy and the
environment as
two specific areas where the two nations should work together.
No
doubt Paulson is sincere when he says what he recommends
for China
is in China’s
own
interest within the context of neo-liberal ideology. Yet Paulson’s
formula for China
is that the US
wants China
to
succeed only on US terms. Paulson’s
approach is based on the assumption that neo-liberal economic reforms
in China
are “necessary to sustain its growth” despite heated policy debate now
raging in
Chinese policy circles on the desirability of such modes of growth.
Paulson
wants China
to open
up Chinese capital markets for “healthy competition” within the
domestic
financial system, so China
can have a currency that is “freely tradable,” despite a history of
financial
crises that befell economies with open financial amrkets and freely
tradable currencies in recent decades.
Paulson
warns Chinese officials they underestimate “at China’s
own peril” the extent to which the currency issue is “viewed by their
critics
as a symbol of unfair competition” even though his own expert opinion
differs
from those held by such uninformed critics. Yet if such critical
complaints are
substantively groundless, any appeasement on them will only lead to
further absurd
demands to perpetuate their anti-China agenda, amounting to “if its not
one
thing, it would be another”. Free traders, of whom Paulson is one,
should not
tolerate political bias to interfere with free trade.
Paulson
calls on China
to press ahead with liberalization across a broad front, including
financial
sector reform, fiscal and regulatory policies to reduce excess savings,
market-based macroeconomic management and enforcement of intellectual
property
rights. “We are taking a comprehensive approach,” he said. “We are
collectively
pulling it together.” Paulson said China
had become a
lightning rod for fears about globalization, but insisted it is
“manageable”.
Paulson’s
neo-liberal message is music to some in China,
particularly his fans in Tsinghua
University,
the bastion of neo-liberal supply-side economics in China.
These reformers would like to see US political pressure push the
Chinese
economy more towards capitalistic market economy, at a time when
Rubinomics, a
set of policies named after Robert Rubin, Treasury Secretary under
President
Clinton, is forced to be on the defensive by rising economic populism
in the US
and around the world. Chinese reformers are similarly put on the
defensive by
glaring defects of their export dominated economic policy, in the form
of
worsening income disparity, life-threatening environmental pollution,
economic
and developmental imbalances, erosion of national spirit and worst of
all,
systemic corruption. China
is not about to drive its economy further down any road that leads to
an economic
equivalent of a dangerous cliff merely to appease US ideological
displeasure.
Chinese Socialism
In an
interview with US
television journalist Mike Wallace on September 2, 1986, Deng Xiao-ping, the
architect of China’s
market reform and open-up policies, responding to a question on
corruption and
other obstacles to foreigners doing business in China,
said:
“I am
aware of these things. They do exist. As we are new to
doing business with the West, it is inevitable that we shall make some
mistakes. I do understand the complaints of foreign investors. No one
would
come here and invest unless he got a return on his investment. We are
taking
effective measures to change the present state of affairs. I believe
that these
problems can be solved gradually. But when they are solved, new
problems will
arise and they, too, should be solved. As leaders, we have to get a
clear
picture of the problems and work out measures to solve them. There is
also the
question of educating the cadres.”
Wallace:
To get rich is glorious. That declaration by
Chinese leaders to their people surprises many in the capitalist world.
What
does that have to do with communism?
Deng:
We went through the “cultural revolution”. During the “cultural
revolution” there was a view that poor communism was preferable to rich
capitalism. After I resumed office in the central leadership in 1974
and 1975,
I criticized that view. Because I did so, I was brought down again. Of
course,
there were other reasons too. I said to them that there was no such
thing as
poor communism. According to Marxism, communist society is based on
material
abundance. Only when there is material abundance can the principle of a
communist society -- that is, “from each according to his ability, to
each
according to his needs” -- be applied. Socialism is the first stage of
communism. Of course, it covers a very long historical period. The main
task in
the socialist stage is to develop the productive forces, keep
increasing the
material wealth of society, steadily improve the life of the people and
create
material conditions for the advent of a communist society.”
Deng
went on: “There can be no communism with pauperism, or
socialism with pauperism. So to get rich is no sin. However, what we
mean by
getting rich is different from what you mean. Wealth in a socialist
society
belongs to the people. To get rich in a socialist society means
prosperity for
the entire people. The principles of socialism are: first, development
of
production and second, common prosperity. We permit some people and
some
regions to become prosperous first, for the purpose of achieving common
prosperity faster. That is why our policy will not lead to
polarization, to a
situation where the rich get richer while the poor get poorer. To be
frank, we
shall not permit the emergence of a new bourgeoisie.”
Deng’s
view of a socialist market economy during the
transition phase from socialism to communism is still the national
purpose of
the People’s Republic, despite the fact that Chinese economic policy
has veered
off course from Deng’s original vision for the decade after the
Tiananmen
incident in 1989. The current leadership is moving to put economic
policy back
on the socialist path and to rein in the excesses of market economy and
address
the imbalances of development approaches that emphasize quantitative
over
qualitative performance.
The
16th Central Committee of the Communist Party of China
(CPC) concluded its fifth plenary session in Beijing
on October 11 2005,
which
examined and approved proposals for formulating the 11th
Five-Year
Plan for National Economy and Social Development. Hu Jintao, general
secretary
of the CPC Central Committee, gave a working report on behalf of the
Political
Bureau of the CPC Central Committee. Premier Wen Jiabao made an
explanation on
the draft proposal.
Premier
Wen Jaibao presented the government’s 2006 Working
Report on March 5, 2005.
The
three sections of the report outlined the government’s workings in
2005, the
direction in which the government would be going in the coming year,
and a
brief outline of China’s
11th Five Year Plan of 2006-2021. Agriculture with the
“Three Rural
Issues” policy (Agriculture, Rural development, Farmer livelihood) was
emphasized throughout the speech, as was the renewed concept of “Govern
for the
People”. Wen strongly
emphasized
help for the poor and closing the wealth gap,
and announced that century-old agriculture taxes on peasants would be
repealed.
China's
new Five-Year Plan, the roadmap for the country's
development in the next five years, will bring revolutionary changes
from the “Getting
Rich First” phase to the “Common Prosperity” phase to bridge the
growing income
and wealth disparity to avoid polarization of society. That is a
historic
adjustment to the pattern of five-year plans since China
changed its approach to economic and social development in the 1970s.
More
than 2 decades after Deng’s reform and open-up policy,
the per capita Gross Domestic Products (GDP) has risen to only $1,700
in 2005 and
is expected to reach only $3,000 in 2020. Even with a purchasing power
parity
of 4:1, Chinese 2005 per capita GDP was $6,800, still substantially
below the US
2005 per capita GDP of $35,000. China
is still, and will continue to be, a poor developing country
notwithstanding
all the glister of high-rise apartment towers and office skyscrapers in
Shanghai.
In
fact, the weakness of China's market-based economic development
record in the past two decades, despite the high price paid in the near
total collapse of its social infrastrcture, life-threatening
environmental degradation, cancerous systemic corruption, intractable
high unemployment and widening income disparity, is its snail-paced
revitalization of the Chinese economy, not the phantom fast progress
that has received much undeserved praise. Compared to other
stagnant developing economies operating under market neoliberalism,
China appears to be a great success, but compared to the
post-WWI achievements of NAZI Germany, which turned a war-devastated
economy in total ruins into the strongest economy in Europe in just
four short years, China's record is at best mediocre.
China's
"rapid" economic growth has also engendered new socio-political
problems that are in danger of outweighing its achievements. The
lowest-income families, comprising the bottom 10% of all families, owns
less
than 2% of all the private assets in the economy, while the
highest-income
families, or the top 10% of all the families, own over 40%.
Chinese
leaders have warned against extremes of poverty and wealth, rising
unemployment
and intensifying social conflict.
“Common
prosperity is not an unreachable
goal, but the basic principle and pursuit of socialism,” said President
Hu
Jin-tao.
The 11th
Five Year Plan recognizes that the
single-minded quest for economic growth does not necessarily lead to
sustainable economic development, and rejects unbalanced quantitative
growth as
the goal of development, putting importance instead on improvements in
the
quality of life. Chinese leaders have of
late repeatedly criticized flawed concepts of economic growth,
asserting that
that the doctrine of “economic development as a focus” should not be
misinterpreted as “speed at all cost.” In the 11th Five-Year
Plan, economic
growth will be measured by “Serving the people to improve their life
quality”
rather than GDP readings.
Yet evidence suggests that speed is not the problem. The problem is the
ineffectiveness of market fundamentalism and excessive reliance on
export as development paths.
Foreign
trade now accounts for over 70% of China's
economy as compared with 24% in the US
economy. Frequent trade frictions with China’s
trade partners have imposed high costs on the Chinese economy. China
has become a major consumer of energy resources in the world.
International energy
institutions predict that from 2002 to 2030 around 21% of the world's
new
demand for energy resources will come from China.
In 2004, nearly 50% of the petroleum used in China
was imported to feed the export sector. When it comes to energy
consumption, China
is merely the kitchen; the dinning room is in the US.
Chinese
planners are working to change the country’s heavy
reliance on foreign investment and resources to secure its national
economy through
energy and capital independence in the next five years. The new
Five-year Plan
will bolster social services to deal with the imbalances in strong
economic growth
and weak social development.
The
problem of social security is particularly serious in
the countryside, where the medical care system and welfare are been
neglected
and allowed to deteriorate in the past 2 decades. During the
period from
1993 to 2003, the number of people with no access to medical insurance
in the
country increased from 900 million to one billion, with the percentage
rising
from 67.8% to 80.7%. The number in the urban area rose from 96.53
million in
1993 to 300 million in 2003. And this is an economy that holds $1
trillion in
foreign reserves.
Structural
demographic dynamics is a ticking time bomb with population
planning conflicting with the need to preserve an operative ratio
between retirees and workers who are expected to support the retirees
with
worker currency income. China's one-child-per-fiamily birth rate is
falling
behind the retirement rate of its workers with dire atuary consequences.
In the
next five years, China
will place more emphasis on science and technology, education and
health care
in policy and investment. All rural children are expected to enjoy
nine-year of free education before 2010, which will reduce farmers'
economic
burden by 100 billion yuan ($12.37 billion) every year. The poor and
the weak
will get more protection and have improved access to social welfare. In all these policy objectives of
socio-economic development, neo-liberal market fundamentalism has very
little
to contribute.
China
Trade Not Unfair to US
Objectively,
the case that Chinese trade with the US
is unfair or damaging to the US
is very weak. The fact is that the terms of US-China trade favors the US
more than it does China.
The US
trade
deficit with its flip side capital account surplus does more for the US
economy than for the Chinese economy.
Conventional
wisdom mistakenly suggests that the US
economy rests precariously on an unsustainable accumulation of debt,
particularly foreign debt. Fueled by government profligacy and low
private
savings rates, the current account deficit and fiscal deficit, the US
has become the world’s largest debtor nation. But the US
is a debtor nation with a difference, for all its debts are denominated
in its
own currency which the US
can print at will.
The
current account deficit is created by the difference
between what US residents spend on imports and what they earn from
exports in a
given year. This deficit now stands at almost 7% of GDP. Total net
foreign
liabilities are now approaching 25% of GDP, but that's less than half
of that of Japan. And China
is now the top trade surplus partner of the US
as well as the top creditor to the US.
While this means China has been shipping real wealth in the form of
goods to
the US in exchange for US dollars it cannot use at home, there is much
talk among
fear-mongering pundits and politicians of the danger of sudden
unwillingness by
investors abroad (read Chinese) to continue adding to their already
large
dollar assets. In this scenario, a panic will cause the dollar to sink,
dollar interest
rates to skyrocket, and the US
economy to descend into crisis, dragging the rest of the world down
with it.
But
the prospect that this scenario will actually come to
pass is nil. This is because economists fail to understand that the
dollar after
it was taken off gold backing is no longer a financial instrument
subject to
market laws of supply and demand. Under dollar hegemony, the dollar is
really a
political instrument. When viewed as a political instrument, everything
that
Larry Summers considered odd about the dollar falls in place logically.
As
long as the US
is the world’s dominant power and the US
economy is the world’s dominant economy in terms of both size and
focus, and
the dollar remains the key reserve currency for world trade, all other
currencies are merely derivatives of the dollar. Derivatives contracts
have profit
or loss with volatility, but such volatility does not threaten the
dollar. The
dollar will rise and fall within a range from its bench mark exchange
rate,
which is the rate the market has come to accept as normal at any given
time. Volatility
in exchange rates is caused by complex factors, mostly technical while
the
fundamentals of dollar hegemony anchor the dollar’s base rate. The base
rate
changes only slowly over the long run, rising according to the quantity
theory
of money as related to the size of the world economy. When the world’s
debt and
commodities are denominated in dollars that only the US
can print, the US
essentially owns all the financial wealth of the world. Foreign-held
dollars
are mere accounting technicalities of little real macro consequence. In
fact,
the more dollars a foreigner holds, the more he/she becomes American.
When China
holds more than a trillion dollars in foreign reserves, it is moving
closer to
become a US
financial colony trapped in domestic poverty.
For
those who spends dollars in their daily activities, such as US
residents,
or most US trans-national corporations, the exchange rate of the dollar
is of
little fundamental relevance. If import prices rise because of a fall
in the
dollar exchange rate, the Federal Reserve, the US central bank, will view it as inflation and
raise dollar interest rates in response, thus pushing the exchange
value of the
dollar back up. The exporting economies will then devalue their
currencies to reset
the price of their exports in dollar terms, or to subsidize it by other
means,
such as lower wages from higher unemployment, or rebates of export
taxes. This
game goes on until fatigue set in to stabilize the bench mark exchange
rate of the dollar.
As long as current US economic and monetary
policies remain unchanged,
the long-term trend of the exchange value of the dollar is down. But
this is not necessary a bad thing for the US. If the down trend of the
dollar is
gradual and moderate, the resultant growth of the US economy will be
able to withstand the dollar's oderly fall which in essence reflects
only the declining share of the US economy in the global economy. Such
a decline does not mean slow growth for the US economy. It can mean
that the world's developing economies will grow at a faster rate than
the
US to reduce the now overweighted US economy when measured by the size
of the US population in global terms. US GDP in 2006 was $13 trillion
with a population of 300 million while China's was $2.5 trillion with a
population of 1.3 billion. By that measure, a case can be made
that the dollar is overweighted and overvalued in a global perspective.
This illustrates the main problem in understanding globalization.
Global
issues are seldom viewed from a global perspective, only from a US
perspective.
US
tax revenue is immune to fluctuations in changes in dollar exchange
rates
because it is denominated in dollars. US
fiscal spending is also immune because it is also denominated in
dollars. With
a falling dollar, US imports prices will rise, forcing more purchases
of
domestic-produced goods by US consumers and more US
exports. But even the current account is immune because it is settled
in
dollars. What will happen is that the face value of the deficit will
not change,
only the actual volume of good bought and sold will change. A fall in
current
account deficit only means less dollars leaving the US
as debt with less dollars returning as capital. As long as US
geopolitical hegemony keep all key commodities denominated in dollars,
no one
who participates in the global economy can escape the dollar, much less
dump
it.
The US
economy
is being held up by dollar asset appreciation which allows higher debt
without
changing debt/equity ratio. There is a torrent of dollar creation by
the Fed but
more by the growth of financial derivatives. This causes three
phenomena:
1)
More
dollars to fund mergers and acquisitions which with increasingly
lame anti-trust regulation, create more efficient monopolies in the
short term thaty may threaten free markets in the long term;
2)
more dollar equity available to company to enable them to
carry more debt for expansion that makes even distressed companies to
look temporarily
healthy, but exposes them to the danger of default if revenue falls
behind debt service ppayments, and
3)
more dollars for investing outside the US
to fund more low-cost export to the US
that will exacerbate the current account deficit problem.
As long as interest
rate, the cost of the use of money
within a time period, is lower than the rate of return on capital, the
economy
will expand by taking on debt. Consequently, corporate earnings will
look
strong as long as US consumers are willing to take on more debt
collateralized
by the rising value of their assets to keep consuming. A
fall in the exchange rate of the dollar will put an abrupt end to this
joy ride.
China
has a
serious structural problem with its export-dominated economy. It
earns dollar income from its oversized export sector but has yuan
expenses in its
anemic domestic market. When the export sector dominated the Chinese
economy, China
is essentially shipping wealth to the US
in exchange for a currency it cannot use at home. China
has accumulated over $1 trillion in foreign reserves, equivalent to its
annual GDP,
yet it does not have enough yuan-denominated money to alleviate
widespread poverty
or to fund its social security obligation or to pay for environmental
restoration. A falling dollar will make China
poorer because its variable income from trade is in fallen dollars and
its fixed expenses at home are
in more expensive yuan. This condition will remain until China
requires payment of its export in yuan and not in dollars, and frees
itself from dollar hegemony.
All
the factor inputs to the Chinese export sector are
imported: capital, loans, energy, technology, design, machine tools,
production
lines, packaging, paper cartons, marketing, transportation and
distribution
systems. These are all dollar costs. To its export sector China
contributes only two under-priced factor inputs: labor and
environmental
pollution. Profits to China
from the Chinese export sector come entirely from low wages and
hidden-cost
pollution. In about 25 years, China
has accumulated over $1 trillion in foreign exchange reserves
equivalent to its
current GDP. China’s
GDP grew at average 10% annually while its foreign exchange reserves
have been
growing at up to 30% 2005 to 2006. For
the last few years China
has been holding back its GDP by over $200 billion every year, sending
the
earnings to finance US
trade deficits, earnings from slave wages and toxic pollution.
What China
needs is to reduce its dollar income and shift that income to yuan by
selling
more of its products in the domestic market. But the entire neo-liberal
globalized
trade is built on all exporting economies thinking earning foreign
exchange is
a good thing.
In the
US,
the decline of labor and environmental inputs has been compensated
by
the increased use of variable inputs and capital. Debt enters into the US
financial system from China
and is re-exported as capital back to China. As for oil consumption, domestic consumption
is 90% supplied from domestic sources. Imported oil feeds mostly China’s
export sector, making China
the kitchen with the US
the dining room.
There
is no way for China
to diversify its foreign currency from dollar assets. The most Ch
can
do is slow the growth of its dollar holdings from its new trade surplus
by
cutting down export. Allotting new Chinese trade surpluses to other
non-dollar
currencies is merely enlarging the volume of dollar derivatives, an
exercise in
circular circuitry.
What China
Needs to Do
What China
needs to do is to keep export to the US
at the same level as imports from the US.
This is easily done. Every 3 months, as soon as export to the US
exceeds export levels, export is stopped until import from the US
catches up. No trade surplus, no new dollar foreign exchange holdings.
The
surplus production is then sold in the domestic market to earn yuan
revenue which
then is re-circulated as higher wages to sustain domestic purchasing
power.
Sovereign credit is used to finance the time gap between rising wages
and
domestic consumption and between corporate sales and rising employment
to
sustain full employment.
This
will
put the trade surplus/exchange rate monkey from China’s
back onto the US’s
back. Prices in the US will rise from a shortage of supply and
dollar
interest rates will rise to fight inflation and the team from
Washington will
beg China to stop this rational nonsense and tell Senators Charles
Schumer (D-NY)
and Graham Senators (R-SC) who are threatening legislation that would
slap a
27.5% tariff on Chinese imports unless China allows the yuan to
appreciate
significantly (20%) to go fishing.
Trade
is a game of market power. The US
needs to recognize that the scale of market power is tilting towards China’s
side and that the US
cannot make hegemonic demands from a position of weakness. The solution
to the US
trade dilemma lies in a reordering of US
trade policy, not on the exchange value of the Chinese currency.
US
geopolitical hegemony rests on an economy that is continually extending
its
lead in the innovation and application of new technology. It does not
rest on
what another country does nor does not do. The fact of the matter is
that
regardless of crybaby complaint of Chinese unfair trade practices,
US-China
trade still benefits the US
more than it does China.
A halt in US-China trade will do more damage to the US
than to China.
The
dollar’s role as the global monetary standard is not threatened, and
the risk
to US
financial
stability posed by large foreign liabilities are exaggerated. The US
economy will adjust to a decline in the dollar and a rise in interest
rates
that will slow the growth of US
consumption and retard its standard of living, but it will not fatally
undermine
the US
economy.
The dislocations and inequities in the US
economy both at home and overseas are caused by dollar hegemony, not by
any
foreign government trade policy. There is a mismatch between the
democratic
process in US politics and the dislocation in the US
economy created by US-led globalization which no amount of China
bashing can resolve.
Dollar Hegemony and
Net International Investment Position
(NIIP)
US external liabilities are
denominated in its own currency,
which remains the key global monetary standard. The net international
investment position (NIIP), the value of foreign assets owned by US
residents
minus the value of US assets owned by nonresidents peaked at almost 13%
of GDP
in 1980. Up until 1989, the US
was a creditor nation. But chronic current account and fiscal deficits
since then
have given the United States
the largest net liabilities in world history.
At the
start of 2004, foreign claims on the US
of $10.5 trillion exceeded US claims of $7.9 trillion abroad, with a
negative
NIIP of $2.6 trillion. In 2005, US NIIP was a negative $2.7 trillion or
21% of
GDP, an increase of $333 billion over the previous year, or 21.6% of
GDP.
The largest share of this debt is in the form of foreigners holding US
sovereign debt. Foreign holdings of US government securities
reached $2.4
trillion in 2005, an increase of $215 billion compared to the previous
year.
The purchases of US government securities by foreign investors financed
two-thirds of the increase in the net US
international liabilities during 2005. US interest payments on this
massive debt
held by foreigners and to foreign holders of US assets means that less
money
will be spent in the US.
Annual US
interest payments on that debt rose to $114 billion, which exceeded
President
Bush’s proposed budget for education, training, employment, and social
services
in 2007 of $86 billion. Normally, these debt payments are
the
Achilles heel of vulnerability as affected by any rise in interest
rates.
But what do foreign interest earners do with their dollar interest
revenue?
They reinvest it in more dollar assets, providing funds for US
investors to buy
foreign assets. A reduction in the US
deficit will upset this
circle of cash flow and cause financial problems in the US
that can quickly translate into political problems for the sitting
administration.
As a
rule, a current account deficit, the broadest measure
of the balance of trade in goods and services, must be financed through
the
sale of US assets to foreign investors and lenders. However, the
$333
billion increase in the net U.S.
liability position in 2005 to a negative $792 billion was considerably
smaller
than the current account deficit of $210 billion for the year, largely
because
of a substantial increase in the value of foreign assets held by US
investors. The market value of foreign stocks held by domestic
investors
alone increased $384 billion in 2005, much more than the $69 billion
increase
in the value of foreign holdings of US stocks. In other words, US
assets are
being swapped for foreign asset at a premium.
Foreign
central banks sharply increased their holdings of US
government securities in 2005, as they purchased dollar assets in order
to keep
the values of their currencies from rising against eh dollar. China
alone increased its holdings of foreign exchange reserves by at least
almost $210
billion in 2005. As a result, the real value of the US dollar
gained 3.7%
in 2005, despite growing trade deficits and the declining NIIP. A rise
in the
exchange value of the yuan against the dollar will mean less Chinese
purchases
of US
sovereign
debt. Does the US
really think that is to its advantage?
NIIP
is measured by two components: 1) direct investment,
the value of domestic operations directly controlled by a foreign
company; and 2)
financial liabilities, the value of stocks, bonds, and bank deposits
held
overseas. At the start of 2004, foreign direct investment in the United
States was $2.4 trillion, while U.S.
direct investment abroad was about $2.7 trillion. US-held
foreign financial assets amounted to
$5.1 trillion while foreign-held US
financial assets amounted to $8.1 trillion, or 74% of GDP. The 2004
NIIP was a
negative $3 trillion, about one third held by China
alone. FDI to China
in 2005 was only $72 billion, about 7% of its foreign reserves.
At the
start of 2004, total US
securities had a market value of $33.4 trillion, about 50% of the world
total.
Foreign investors held more than 38% of the $4 trillion in US Treasury
bonds,
but only 11% of the $6.1 trillion in agency bonds (such as those issued
by
Fannie Mae and Freddie Mac); 23% of the $6.5 trillion in corporate
bonds; and
11% of the $15.5 trillion in equities outstanding. These foreign
liabilities
are the result of a string of current account deficits that have grown
from 1.5%
of GDP in the mid-1990s to 7% of GDP, about $805 billion, in 2005.
Economists
at the Organization for Economic Cooperation and Development (OECD)
estimate
that ongoing deficits of 3 percent of GDP would bring the US NIIP to
negative 40%
of GDP by 2010, and that it would eventually stabilize at around
negative 63%.
If the deficit remains at today's level, they foresee the NIIP growing
to
negative 50% of GDP by 2010 and eventually to negative 100%.
Yet
future dollar depreciation and market adjustments in
interest rates and asset prices will likely check the negative increase
of the
NIIP. Dollar depreciation against the euro and the yen in 2002, 2003
and 2004 kept
the NIIP flat despite rising current account deficits. Under dollar
hegemony, chronic US
current
account deficits reflect strong economic fundamentals rather than fatal
structural flaws. The problem with US
trade policy is not economic but political fallouts from unbalanced
dislocations such as income disparity and sector-related job loss.
Three Ways to Look
at the Trade Deficit
A trade-oriented approach views US
current account deficits
as a byproduct of robust economic growth, reinforced by an overvalued
dollar
and the US
economy’s structural import bias. In this view, the U.S. has a stubborn
current
account deficit because it grows both faster and with more efficiency
than its
trading partners and spends a disproportionate share of its growing
income on
imported goods and services to further accelerate its economic
development paid
for with debt denominated in dollars that the US can print at will.
A
related perspective blames low domestic saving for the
danger of trade deficits, fearing that a sudden reluctance by
foreigners to
continue exporting their excess savings to the US
would send the US
economy into financial crisis. But US saving is stronger than
government
statistics show. Capital gains on equities, 401(k) plans, and home
market values
even after coming correction, which add up to 20% of GDP, are excluded
from
measurements of personal saving. The national account also excludes
“intangible” investment: spending on knowledge-creating activities such
as
on-the-job training, new-product development and testing, design and
development,
and managerial time spent on workplace organization. Economists at the
National
Bureau of Economic Research estimate that intangible investment grew
rapidly
during the 1990s and is now at least as large as physical investment in
plant
and equipment: more than $1 trillion per year, or 10% of GDP.
Consequently, the
size and growth rate of the US
economy have been seriously underestimated by the neglect of stealth
saving.
A
third approach to the current account deficit focuses on
the growth and composition of global wealth. In this framework,
international
capital movements drive the current account balance, rather than vice
versa.
With the US
expected to grow faster than Europe and Japan
over the next several decades and wealth growing rapidly in Asia,
especially in China
and India,
foreign
wealth will continue to flock to US financial markets. This could
generate a
sequence of U.S.U.S.
assets; NIIP ratios that appear dangerously high relative to US GDP
would still
be sustainable because of the rapid growth of global wealth. The only obstacle is political restrictions
put on foreign acquisition of US assets. deficits
as high as
5% of GDP, causing the NIIP to balloon. But such an
increase would not mean an end to the foreign appetite for US assets; NIIP
ratios that appear
dangerously high relative to US GDP
would still be sustainable because of the rapid growth of global
wealth. The only obstacle is political restrictions put on foreign
aquisition of US assets.
US
financial markets have stayed strong even as the
financing of the US
deficit shifts from private investors to foreign central banks. From
2000 to
2003, the official institutional share of investment inflows rose from
4% to 30%.
A large percentage of the $1.3 trillion in Asian government foreign
exchange
reserves is in US
assets. Central banks now claim about 12% of total foreign-owned assets
in the United States,
including more than $1 trillion in
Treasury and agency securities. Official inflows from Asia
will likely continue for the foreseeable future, keeping US interest
rates from
rising too fast and choking off investment. Yet US
phobia against government ownership versus private ownership will
eventually
make this trend a political problem.
Senator
Schumer charges China
with pursuing a “mercantilist” development strategy of undervalued
exchange
rates to support export-led growth at the expense of the US. This is uninformed grandstanding because
mercantilism has to do with gold-backed specie currency, not a fiat
currency as
the dollar. Under dollar hegemony, China
must continue to finance US imports of its exports, since the US
is its largest market and a major source of inward direct investment.
Only a
fundamental transformation in China’s
development and growth strategy could undermine this unequal terms of
trade, an
unlikely prospect as long as Chinese policy makers remain under the
toxic spell
of snake-oil neo-liberalism. The biggest threat to U.S.
hegemony stems not from the sentiments of foreign investors, but from
protectionism and isolationism at home.
For China,
US
protectionism will force it to turn from export toward domestic
development. Mao
Zedong said that bad things could be turned into good things. Such a
shift will
liberate China
from its slippery path into a comprador mode of development back on the
track
of economic self-determination.
A Strategic Economic
Dialogue
Since assuming office on July
3, 2006, Secretary Paulson has put together a
“strategic economic dialogue” that began in September. A key to the
success of
this potentially highly useful dialogue is to not to push China in the
direction as a cheap labor colony of the US, but to allow China to
develop as a
powerful engine of growth for Asia and the global economy. To do that China
must be wean from its current addition to labor-intensive export and
redirect
its energy toward domestic development not from foreign capital but
with
sovereign credit. Only a vibrant Chinese economy that trades with the US
as an equal partner can set the US
free from the ironic problem that dollar hegemony has created for its
economy.
Representative
Nancy Pelosi, the California Democrat who is
to serve as Speaker of the House next year, who has earned a string of
misguided anti-China medals during her political career, has already
signaled a
tougher line on China,
raising the stakes for the Treasury secretary. “Many of us in the
Congress will
be watching closely for tangible results from Secretary Paulson’s
trip,” Ms.
Pelosi said through a spokesman, asserting that the administration’s
policies
on China
have
generally been ineffective across the board. The tangible results, if
they come
to pass, will be a hard landing for the US
economy. The incoming Speaker needs to understand that US-China trade
is a key
factor behind this Goldilocks US economy.
In his
first speech, Paulson said: “These challenges are
made even more difficult by the fact that within China,
as in the U.S.,
there are loud voices espousing anti-reform, protectionist sentiment.
In China
this resistance stems from a number of factors including that the
benefits of
this economic expansion have been spread unevenly among its citizens
and that
some influential people have never fully embraced the need to open up
the
Chinese economy to competition. This protectionist sentiment is
evidenced by
increasing levels of public discontent, demonstrations, and anti-reform
articles written by prominent academics.”
The Wealth and Income Gap
The widening gap between the richest and
poorest US residents has not the focus of attention by anyone in
the Bush
administration until Henry Paulson, the new Treasury Secretary who sees
it as a
long-term economic policy challenge. Paulson appears to attempt to
reframe the
policy debate on this fundamental issue as a solution to the trade
problem.
The trade problem is rooted in global income inequality which is a
problem that
the US
cannot
solve without first addressing its domestic income inequality.
The wealth gap is a fixture of the
industrialization phase of US economic
history but relative income equality has been the dynamo of the US
consumer economy. Fordism put the US on the
road to rising industrial wages to create the US middle
class out of factory workers and allow the US
economy to overtake its older European competitors. The two world wars
gave US
workers income growth that consistently outstripped inflation and
allowed productivity
growth to sustain spectacular growth of consumer demand, a key
component in the
success of the US economy.
Market capitalism naturally produces income
disparity and polarization that lead to recurrent economic crises. To
correct
this structural flaw, the nation adopted an income policy. Income
redistribution has been the tradition of the US tax
regime since the New Deal. With the onset of 8 years of supply-side
“Reaganomics”,
followed by another 8 years of
neo-liberal “Rubinomics” under Clinton, whom orthodox liberals
Democrats accuse
as the best Republican president in history, inequality has been
growing in US
society to fuel a vibrant economy. While the Republicans adopted a new
income
policy to redistribute income upward with the watering down of the
progressive
income tax, the neo-liberal Clinton Democrats used outsourcing in a
globalized
market economy kept US wages from rising, and built a fiscal surplus by
starving
social spending. The nest result is to expand the globalized economy at
the
expense of the US domestic economy.
For the past two decades, two-party democracy
has failed to provide alternative choices in economic policy for the US
electorate. And outsourcing is not the only factor driving US wages
down, even
as average worker productivity within the US has surged, average hourly
earnings have stagnated, while the nation’s economic elites have
prospered with
astronomical levels of incomes. New sectors such as the high-tech,
information
technology and financial services operate on the model of low salaries
and high
stock options. Even for investors, the trend has been to favor equity
appreciation over dividend income. Neo-liberal economist seemed to have
forgotten
the basic rule in finance: Income is all. Economic growth without
income is a
fantasy.
Income
disparity has now reached obscene levels. Capital One
Financial CEO Richard Fairbank exercised 3.6 million options for gains
of
nearly $250 million, on which he pay tax on the lower capital gain rate
rather
the income tax rate. His personal take exceeded the annual corporate
profits of
more than half of the Fortune 1000 companies, including
Goodyear Tire
& Rubber, Reebok and Pier One. Median pay among chief executives
running
most of the nation's 100 largest companies soared 25% to $17.9 million
in 2005,
dwarfing the 3.1% average gain by typical US
workers. And Congress is in the midst of a passionate debate over
raising the
minimum wage from the current $5.15 an hour to $7.25 an hour in 2009 in
three
steps, with opponents to the proposed bill claiming that such a raise
would
destroy the US
economy. The
idea of indexing the minimum wage to inflation is considered a
legislative non-starter.
US
corporate earnings are at an all-time high because wages
have been stagnant. Corporations are overflowing with cash but they
refuse to
pass it on to their workers. Instead corporations adopt share buybacks
scheme
with the surplus cash to raise the market value of the stocks.
To his
credit, Paulson is the first Treasury Secretary in
recent history to focus on the inequality problem. In his first major
speech as
Treasury secretary, Paulson said: “Amid this country's strong economic
expansion, many Americans simply aren't feeling the benefits. Their
increases
in wages are being eaten up by high energy prices and rising healthcare
costs,
among others.” Paulson gave notice that this issue will be a priority
in his
agenda to restructure the US
economy.
A
Federal Reserve survey shows that between 2001 and 2004,
the median income of US workers with college degrees barely budged,
rising from
$72,300 to $73,000, after adjusting for inflation. Clinton
Administration did
almost nothing to advance the interests of organized labor or working
people
more generally. Union membership continued its long decline during the Clinton
presidency, standing at 13.5 percent of the total workforce when he
left office. A paper co-authored by Rubin
observed: “Prosperity
has neither trickled down nor rippled outward. Between 1973 and 2003,
real GDP
per capita in the United States
increased 73 percent, while real median hourly compensation rose only
13
percent.”
New Populism Against
Rubinomics
A new
wave of economic populism is surging along with Democratic
victory at the
polls. Yet these new populists seem to exclusively target foreign
trade, not
realizing that the imbalance trade is the result rather than the cause
of the
new age of economic inequality, the fountainhead of which originated in
US domestic
policy. If Paulson really wants to deal with the problem of persistent
US trade
deficits, the solution lies not in Beijing, but at home in the US.
The
new populists argue that the trade agreements beginning
with NAFTA and continuing through the various World Trade Organization
negotiations have failed to protect workers’ rights to organize unions
and thus
raise wages in the low-wage countries. Instead, wages in high wage
countries
have continued to stagnate or drift downwards in real purchasing power.
They
also insist not only on an increase in the minimum wage but on tying it
to the
cost of living so that future inflation will not erode its real value,
as it
has in the past.
Just
as the neo-conservatives have hijacked foreign policy
in the Bush Administration, the neo-liberal Clinton
wing of the Democratic Party hijacked the party’s economic policies.
The Clinton
neo-liberals imported the Republican ideology that the economy could
achieve
sustained growth only if markets were allowed to operate unregulated
globally.
Treating labor as a captured constituency, the Clinton
administration vigorously supported free trade agreements like Nafta
and agreed
to China’s
admission into the World Trade Organization (WTO) to expand the global
economy
at the expanse of the US
domestic economy, with half-hearted promises of worker retraining and
other
safety-net measures that Clinton’s
balanced budget could not fund. The adverse effects of Reubinomics were
masked
by a temporary burst of unsustainable economic prosperity caused by
corporate
and consumer debt.
The
new populists want an alternative to Rubinomics, one
that register growths by the income received by the middle class. They
argue
that the national income has increasingly flowed disproportionately
into corporate
profit and the rich. They call for a review of US-led globalization and
for new
terms of trade that do not put the cost of economic expansion entirely
on the chronic
poor, the newly poor and the powerless both domestically and globally.
They
call for government regulation in the terms of trade to distribute the
benefits
more equitably.
The
free traders accused the new populists of being
protectionists. Rubin admits that globalization has not brought job
security or
rising incomes to US workers and that as the global economy expands to
benefit
the US
in
general, it does so at the expense of shrinking the US
middle class’ share of the economic pie. Yet Rubinomists stick to the
worn-out
Maragret Thatcher claim of TINA (There is no alternative), arguing that
regulating trade and imposing market restrictions would be
self-defeating. There
is now enough historical data to question the false claim of benefits
of financial
globalization which has brought about monetary and financial crises
around the
world every few years. The emergence of unregulated capital, debt and
currency
markets has prevented government around the world to effectively use
sovereign
credit to finance domestic development and force all nations to
distorting their
economies toward over-reliance on exports for dollars and to compete by
joining
the race to the bottom on wages and environmental abuse.
And it
is not clear that Rubinomics was really responsible
for economic growth of the 1990s. Historical data suggest that the
information
revolution greatly improved productivity even in economies insulated
from
Rubinomics, such as China
and India.
The
free market does not know best. Left undirected, a free market will
race ahead at unsafe speed towards accidents waiting to happen.
A
more balanced US economic policy away
from maximization of profits might have let that
productivity burst lift the global economy into a higher plane without
distortions that are haunting it now.
In his
2003 book, In an Uncertain World, Rubin
admits: “In retrospect, the
effect of the Clinton
economic plan
on business and consumer confidence may have been even more important
than the
effect on interest rates.” Business investment during the Clinton
boom years was not exceptional vigorous. It was the brain-power
intensive
information revolution that helped trigger big gains in productivity
and growth
despite a comparative low capital input compared to earlier
capital-intensive
cycles, such as the railroad age.
The
1997 Economic Report of the President released in
February, five months before the 1997 Asian financial crisis, predicted
that
growth would average a meager 2.2% over the next four years. The actual
growth
rate turned out to be 3.9%, almost twice. A case can be made that the
high
growth rate was the result of the Fed’s monetary easing in response to
the Asian
financial crises which started on July 2, 1997 in Thailand
and whirled around Asia via contagion like a
tornado.
When contagion hit Wall Street in October, the Fed did what no other
central
banks could do. It printed dollars to provide liquidity to the US
banking
system to not only contain the crisis, but also to allow US banks to
buy up
distressed Asia assets at fire sale prices. It was a clear example of
how
dollar hegemony works.
“Rubinomics”
is a doctrine of aggressive trade
liberalization paid for by squeezing domestic and foreign workers while
balancing
the fiscal budget at home by cutting social programs to avoid the need
for raising
taxes progressively. The Clinton Federal surplus came directly from the
pockets
of workers. Yet Rubin has said publicly that he understands that income
inequality, both domestic and around the world, will produce a
political
backlash at the core that threatens the neo-liberal trading system,
even the
stability of capitalistic democracy. Rubin acknowledges the ill effect
of globalization
on US wages which takes on political significance when the squeeze
shift from
just the poor who seldom vote, to the politically active middle class.
The
favoritism of government policy towards the rich, particularly the tax
structure, has become so embarrassingly obscene that even the super
rich such
as Warren Buffet complained about its unfairness.
Rubin
has launched the Hamilton Project, a policy group of
like-minded economists and financiers who are developing ameliorative
measures
to aid the threatened workforce and to create a broader political
constituency
that will defend the trading system against populist backlash. Yet how
can one
defend a system that creates wealth by making the majority poor? It is
not
possible to deify Mammon, the demon of the love of money.
The
populist tidal wave may well build up to tsunami scale.
As outsourcing move up the skill ladder, threatening the job security
of not
just assembly line workers, but highly educated, resourceful and active
workers
in high-tech, information technology, medicine and finance, the
democratic
process will turn against neo-liberal globalization. The backlash can
turn
ugly, mixing xenophobia with anti-Semitism.
The
neo-conservative Weekly Standard observes correctly that
wages have been stagnant because the increases in compensation have
been eaten
out by soaring health care costs. Yet both neoconservatives and
conservatives oppose
universal health care as socialistic. The
Weekly Standard proposes “outsourcing
healthcare services to cheaper
foreign countries where highly qualified medical professionals working
with the
latest equipments only charge less than a fraction of the fees in the US.
Some corporations have already started doing this, and the results so
far have
been very positive.” The American Medical Association, the conservative
trade
lobby for doctors, will soon join the march against globalization.
Neo-conservatives
Defend Globalization
Globalization
is being defended by neo-conservatives who are
strange bed-fellows of neo-liberals. The Weekly Standard wades in: “It
is
estimated that of the 28 Democrats who beat GOP House incumbents on
Election
Day, 22 are unabashed protectionists, with five being pragmatic
protectionists.
All six losing GOP senators were free traders. Even free trader Jim
Jeffords of Vermont
is being replaced by the
reliably anti-globalization Bernie Sanders. There is a new scent in the
air,
and if you're not convinced, consider the life and times of Lou Dobbs.
The CNN
television host suffered for years from flat ratings as the young
upstart Fox
News regularly cleaned his clock. Then Dobbs began pounding the
anti-globalization
theme, night after night bemoaning the American jobs lost to foreign
competition.
His ratings suddenly shot up by more than a third.”
Free
trade still has one reliable defender: the presidential
veto which the Democrats do not have the vote to override for the next
two
years.
A False Debate
Yet
the debate on globalization is between two extremes
rather than seeking solutions. International trade is very desirable if
it
augments domestic development. Unfortunately, in the last two decade,
international trade has turned itself into an inhibitor of domestic
development. This is because the destructiveness of dollar hegemony
which
forces all economies to suppress domestic wages and development to
compete for
export to earn dollars which cannot be used at home. What is needed is
a new
international finance architecture that allows export payments to be
denominated in the exporting country’s currency so that domestic
development
can be financed with sovereign credit without having to resort to
importing
foreign capital. Concurrently, growth
needs to be measured not in terms of how many workers are laid off from
mergers
and acquisition in the name of efficiency, but by how many new jobs are
created
by improving productivity with new technology. A corporate tax regime
should be
introduced to discourage obscene profits so that earnings can be
channeled more
equitably back into wages to stimulate consumer demand to reduce
overcapacity
in the economy.
These
are the issues that Paulson and his team should be
exploring with their Chinese counterparts in the “strategic economic
dialogue” to
develop a symbiotic trade relationship between the two major economies
that will
augment urgently needed domestic development. There is no sense kicking
around
dead horse issues like exchange rates and intellectually property
rights. |
|
|
|
|