|
World
Order, Failed States and Terrorism
PART 6: Outsourcing Public Security
By
Henry C K Liu
PART 1: The
failed-state cancer
PART 2: The
privatization wave
PART 3: The business of private security
PART 4: Militarism
and mercenaries
PART 5: Militarism
and the war on drugs
This article appeared in AToL
on April 9, 2005
Public security is the prime function of government. Public security is
supposed to be provided by government to all citizens equally
regardless of levels of wealth. It is one of the basic political goods
government is obliged to provide equally to all. It is as sacred to
democracy as the principle of one person, one vote.
When public security is privatized, there is a structural danger that
adequate protection, or at least added protection needed to meet newly
perceived threats, is available only to those who can afford to pay for
it. When the rich and the corporate population can get additional
needed security from private contractors for a fee, political pressure
on government to provide adequate public security for the general
public is invariably weakened, just as the proliferation of private
education reduces political pressure to improve public education. With
income disparity increasingly institutionalized in market economies,
the privatization of public security amounts to institutionalizing
inequality in government protection, just as the privatization of other
government services institutionalizes inequality in the delivery of
other basic political goods by government. The US Supreme Court has
long since declared the segregation of education by race
unconstitutional, yet segregation of education by wealth continues to
be widely accepted in the United States, despite an obvious coincidence
between race and poverty.
In response to increasingly inadequate security protection provided by
government against rising levels of threat from terrorism and crime, a
key characteristic of failed statehood, private security services have
emerged as a major business sector. Government policies in recent
decades have institutionalized income disparities, leading to trends of
increased needs for government protection from threats generated by
breakdowns in social cohesion; yet such increased needs are left
unequally met by trends to privatize government services. Such a
combination of trends erodes the role of government at both ends and is
the most glaring evidence of the failed-state syndrome.
Security in the homeland
In recent years, the US government has escalated its commitment of
funding to homeland-security needs. Including supplemental funding, the
federal budget allocated only US$17 billion ($62 per capita) to
homeland security in fiscal year 2001, which ended on September 30,
when, until September 11 of that year, massively destructive threats
from terrorism had still been just a theoretical proposition. The
homeland-security budget after September 11, 2001, increased to $29
billion ($105 per capita) in fiscal year 2002. In fiscal year 2003, the
federal budget for homeland-security activities was $38 billion ($135
per capita). In fiscal year 2005, it was $45.9 billion ($164 per
capita). President George W Bush administration's budget request for
fiscal year 2006 calls for $49.9 billion ($169 per capita) in total
funding for homeland security, an increase of approximately 8.6% in
real (inflation-adjusted) terms over the fiscal year 2005 budget. While
the rate of rise in federal expenditure has moderated, the rate of
increase in the need for homeland security has not. The slowdown in the
rise in the federal budget for homeland security can only be explained
by a shift of the cost to the private sector.
A 2003 review by the Federal Reserve Bank of New York (FRBNY) suggests
that the economic impact of increased homeland-security spending will
be relatively small, and that it is unlikely to have major effects on
the fiscal discipline of the government or on productivity in the
private sector. Government spending on homeland security accounted for
0.35% of gross domestic product (GDP) in 2003 - an amount only
one-tenth the size of national-defense outlays. In conjunction with
this spending, even if the private sector were to double its
security-related inputs, the report estimates that the total annual
direct costs of homeland security would be only $72 billion, or 0.66%
of 2003 GDP. Moreover, such a doubling of inputs would at most reduce
the private sector's labor productivity level by only 1.12%.
The report attaches two caveats to its conclusion. First, the results
do not suggest that the economic damage of the September 11 terrorist
attacks is negligible. The findings focus solely on the economic
effects of the expenditures undertaken to prevent and prepare for
future incidents. Second, the results do not suggest that homeland
security is unimportant. The study is in essence focused only on the
cost side of a cost-benefit analysis. The benefits of homeland security
are not easy to measure. One simply cannot estimate or verify how many
terrorist activities, if any, are being prevented because of increased
security measures, or that if and when an catastrophic attack does take
place, how much of its likelihood of occurrence would have been reduced
by added security spending.
Clearly, it is difficult to put a value on the heightened sense of
safety that the homeland-security program provides. If such a program
is viewed as insurance against loss from terrorist catastrophe, then
the absence of catastrophe will have justified the cost of the
insurance. Yet the value of prevention is not automatically positive. A
false sense of security can come from the power of suggestion that when
something is being done, some positive effect will result. It is known
as the Hawthorne Effect, named after the General Electric Co experiment
in Hawthorne, New York, to search for optimum lighting levels for
highest efficiency in productivity by varying the levels of lighting.
The experiment discovered that changes in lighting levels caused
productivity to increase more than any fixed level of lighting. Workers
are energized when they feel that they are being fussed over.
However, real prevention depends on the real effectiveness of the
spending. If directed toward wrong targets, spending may not prevent
anything. Worse yet, it may divert focus and resources from the real
targets. Nevertheless, given the relatively small expense of prevention
as compared with the cost of failure, proponents of the
homeland-security program argue that even if it should prevent just one
major incident over the next several years, the return on
homeland-security expenditures would more than justify the cost.
Further, spending buys political coverage from criticism of officials
and administrations. Unfortunately, the same generous rationale is not
applied to the expenditure of removing the root causes of terrorism,
ie, global socio-economic injustice.
Privatization of homeland security reduces government expenditure by
shifting part of the cost to the private sector. Private security
spending contributes more than government spending to increases in GDP,
and thus it minimizes the economic burden of security. The way the US
plans to keep the increased cost of homeland security to minimum
adverse economic impact is through the voodoo magic of input-output
econometrics. When homeland security is privatized, its expenditure
becomes a growth industry. Thus, by the rules of econometrics,
preventing loss from threats to homeland security is an input, and
security spending becomes an output that adds to GDP and creates little
adverse impact on the economy as a whole, albeit the price is systemic
inequality of protection. Further, econometric analysis ignores the
fact that if the need for security is reduced, the output could have
been directed toward more constructive uses.
For example, after September 11, the US Congress provided the
pharmaceutical industry with incentives to develop drugs for
terrorism-related illnesses, including protection from normal product
liability and proposals to extend patent rights on medication unrelated
to homeland security. This reduces the expenditure of government
research, but raised the price of drugs generally by delaying the
entrance of generic drugs that are cheaper than brand-name drugs.
The measure of economic failure
The science of econometrics deals with economic measurements used to
estimate the magnitude of quantitative relationships among economic
variables within a model of the economy. It is used to test hypotheses
and forecast outcomes, with wide application to business forecasting
and market planning. There are two kinds of economic variables in a
model: endogenous variables that are found within the model; and
exogenous variables that are introduced from outside the model.
Security threats are exogenous variables in an econometric model since
their levels and intensity are independent of the internal construct of
the model. Economists seek insights by examination of data. This is
known as the inductive approach. They also attempt to validate or
disprove existing theories by comparing theoretical claims against
empirical data. This is known as the hypothetical approach. The two
approaches are not mutually exclusive, their difference is analogous to
different starting points in a conceptual circle.
William Stanley Jevons (1835-82), an English economist and logician,
simultaneously with Viennese economist Carl Menger and French economist
Leon Walras launched the Marginalist Revolution of 1871-74 (diminishing
marginal utility) that gave rise five decades later to neo-classical
economics, which emphasizes the phenomenon of exchange over production.
Marginalist theory of value puts forth the idea that the "natural
value" of a good is determined only by its subjective scarcity, ie the
degree to which people's desire for that good exceeds its availability.
When clean water was in abundance, it had no economic value, even
though its value to life is paramount. When industrialization pollutes
the Earth's water supply, clean water commands a high price. Thus
pollution, like security threats, serves an economic function in
neo-classical economics. Privatization of water depends on water
pollution for its economic justification.
The focus on scarcity is behind the rise of market capitalism where
price is not determined by the cost of production but by scarcity of
supply. The cost of oil production remains around $4 a barrel on land
and $7 a barrel offshore. It is scarcity that has driven the price of
oil above $50 per barrel in recent months. The cost of production for
additional copies of Microsoft's Windows is near zero, yet each copy
can sell for $200 because Microsoft controls the supply through its
intellectual property rights.
Marginal utility gives rise to market failure through the emergence of
monopolies and cartels whose purpose is to keep prices high by limiting
supply rather than increasing production. It robs society of the
material benefits of rising productivity from advanced technology.
Surplus food from efficient agro-technology is dumped in the sea to
keep prices high while billions starve around the world. Money is
constantly kept scarce to maintain its value while poverty is kept
widespread in a world of idle production overcapacity made possible by
technological progress. If overcapacity were to be fully utilized,
prices would have to fall or wages would have to rise to increase
public purchasing power to absorb the added products. Both options are
destabilizing to the state of scarcity without which the entire science
of economics would have to be rethought. Thus workers are kept
unemployed or underemployed to cut down on the production of goods they
cannot afford on their low wages. The concept of marginal utility has
created as much misery for mankind as racism, by keeping basic human
needs at a constant level of scarcity. States that tolerate a failed
market are by definition failed states.
In 1803, Jean-Baptiste Say (1767-1832), in examining the evolution of
trade between Britain and Brazil, observed that demand for a particular
set of goods can only be expressed by equivalent supply of another set.
Supply, therefore, "creates" its own demand. Almost all of classical
and most neo-classical theory is based on this simple, even
tautological, assertion. Say's Law concludes that general gluts cannot
exist. Classical economists assert that unemployment and market
failures were due to excess supplies over demands of particular
commodities and not excess supplies (or gluts) of commodities generally
as a whole. David Ricardo (1772-1823) notes: "Mistakes can be made, and
commodities not suited to demand may be produced - of these there may
be a glut" and that "it is at all times the bad adaptations of the
commodities produced to the wants of mankind which is the specific
evil, and not the abundance of commodities. Demand is only limited by
the will and power to purchase." John Stuart Mill (1806-73) concurs by
noting that in these situations, "production is not excessive, but
merely ill-assorted". Ricardo and Mill extended this proposition to
savings and investment. If one produces more than one consumes, then
the surplus is saved and, by definition of terms, invested. No one
would produce in excess of consumption needs if one does not have a
desire either to exchange it or invest it. Supply, therefore, generates
demand. This relationship virtually all the classical economists held
to be an irrefutable truth.
Thomas Robert Malthus (1766-1834) and French economist J C L Simonde de
Simonde (1773-1842) are the exceptions who believed general gluts could
exist. They reasoned that income is distributed among workers,
entrepreneurs and landowners receiving wage income, profit and land
rents respectively. And landowners will receive a portion of income,
but they may choose not to consume it. And when they don't, there will
be a general glut (excess supply of goods) even though the
investment-savings identity still holds. Thus all classical economists,
except for Malthus and Simonde, were generally in agreement over the
validity of Say's Law, at least in the long run. They all also agree on
the identity of savings and investment as well as the separation of
output from price theory. The most famous under-consumption cycle
theory was laid out by John Maynard Keynes in his General Theory (1936).
The neo-classical story is often captured in diagrammatic form by the
idea that equilibrium prices and quantities of goods are determined
jointly and simultaneously by the demand and supply for goods. Yet
demand is blocked by the need to skim off surplus value in the form of
return on capital through profits, which can only come from lowering
wages before the level of cost of material and capital needed to
produce goods. Price is always the sum of cost of material, capital and
labor. Of the three costs, labor is the only flexible variable. Yet if
wages consistently fall below the level of prices for goods, a downward
spiral of overproduction and unemployment will result, which is the
basis of business cycles and long waves.
According to the theory of marginal utility, since fear drives up
demands for security, the demand and therefore the price for private
security will rise if the supply of government provided security is
reduced. Higher prices for private security are not inflationary if the
value of the benefit (perceived safety) also rises. Thus rising fear
from terrorism is good economics in that it creates rising demand for
private security services at rising prices that are not inflationary
because of rising fear, and contributes to a rising GDP. Such is the
warped logic of econometrics employed by the FRBNY review on the
economic impact of terrorism-induced homeland-security expenditure.
The inductive approach has a long history of producing esoteric, at
times bizarre theories. Jevons discerned from data evidence of a
sunspot-driven business cycle (1875, 1884). Clement Juglar (1819-1905),
a French doctor, statistician and father of business-cycle theory, was
an early proponent (1862) of the development of an economic theory of
the business cycle by identifying the "Juglar seven-to-11-year
industrial cycle" that has since been associated with his name. His
findings on credit cycles spurred the subsequent efforts of
overinvestment theorists. Juglar saw in financial tables evidence for a
credit-driven cycle. Similarly, Henry Ludwell Moore (1869-1958), a
student of Menger in Vienna and an early disciple of Walras in France,
was the only American member of the original Lausanne School grouping
around the Frenchman Walras and the Italian Vilfredo Pareto. The
central attribute of the Lausanne School was its development of general
equilibrium theory and its extension of the applicability of the
neo-classical approach to economics. Moore also delved deeply into
discovering the connection between commodity business cycles and
equilibrium theory. His theory of the cycle was externally driven by
eight-year cycles of rainfall. His magnum opus, Synthetic Economics
(1929), was a Herculean attempt to estimate
Walras' general equilibrium system. Moore used the inductive approach
in 1914 to argue for a weather and astral-driven cycle.
The hypothetical approach was also used by economists to attempt to fit
data to demand curves, as represented by Nikolai D Kondratiev
(1892-1931?), Russian economist and founder of the Moscow Institute for
Business Conditions. Kondratiev identified the half-century "long wave"
in his famous 1922 tract and 1926 article "The Long Waves in Economic
Life". One of the architects of the first Soviet Five Year Plan, he was
imprisoned in a Siberian camp in which he died some time in the 1930s.
Wesley C Mitchell and the National Bureau of Economic Research (NBER)
used the hypothetical approach in their research. NBER today is the
official diagnostician of recessions in the US economy. The measurement
of business cycles was the main topic in the hypothetical approach. The
NBER does not record Kondratiev Cycles (or "long waves") as its
researchers do not believe these cycles exist. Nonetheless, four
Kondratiev waves have been identified:
1. The Industrial Revolution (1787-1842) is
the most famous Kondratiev wave: the boom began in about 1787 and
turned into a recession at the beginning of the Napoleonic age in 1801
and, in 1814, deepened into a depression. The depression lasted until
about 1827, after which there was a recovery until 1842. As is obvious,
Kondratiev rode on the development of textile, iron and other
steam-powered industries after 1842.
2. The Bourgeois Kondratiev (1843-1897):
After 1842, the boom re-emerged and a new Kondratiev wave began, this
one as a result of the railroad age in Northern Europe and the US and
the accompanying expansion in the coal and iron industries. The boom
ended approximately in 1857 when it turned into a recession. The
recession turned into a depression in 1870, which lasted until about
1885. The recovery began after that and lasted until 1897.
3. The Neo-Mercantilist Kondratiev (1898-1950?):
The boom began about 1898 with the expansion of electric power and the
automobile industry and lasted until about 1911. The recession that
followed turned into depression in about 1925 and lasted until around
1935. This third wave entered into a recovery immediately afterward,
which one might suspect lasted until around 1950.
4. The Fourth Kondratiev (1950- 2010?). There
has been much debate among believers on the dating of the fourth wave,
largely because of the confusions generated by the low fluctuation in
price levels and the issue of Keynesian policies, and hence this debate
is yet to be resolved. Perhaps the most acceptable set of dates is that
the boom began around 1950 and lasted until about 1974, wherein
recession set in. When (and if) this recession fell into its depression
phase may be more difficult to ascertain (circa 1981?), but what has
been more or less agreed upon is that in 1992 (or thereabouts) the
recovery began and has been projected to give way to a boom, and thus a
new Kondratiev wave, around 2010 or so.
Simon Kuznets (1901-85), neither a Keynesian nor an econometrician,
took his cues from Mitchell's institutionalism. His initial work was on
the empirical analysis of business cycles (1930) - a 15-20-year cycle
he identified was later attached to his name, the "Kuznets Cycle".
Kuznets was also one of the earliest workers on developmental
economics, in particular collecting and analyzing the empirical
characteristics of developing countries. His major thesis, which argued
that underdeveloped countries of today possess characteristics
different from those that industrialized countries faced before they
developed, helped put an end to the simplistic view that all countries
went through the same "linear stages" in their history and launched the
separate field of development economics - which now focused on the
analysis of modern underdeveloped countries' distinct experiences.
Among his several discoveries that sparked important theoretical
research programs was that of the inverted U-shaped relation between
income inequality and economic growth; he also discovered the patterns
in savings-income behavior. Kuznets won the Nobel Prize for economics
in 1971 while he was at Harvard University.
Private security industry giants
Wackenhut Services, a subsidiary of the Wackenhut Corp, provides
security services to private and public clients, including facilities
operations and maintenance, emergency preparation and response, fire
protection, hazardous-material management, and security and
law-enforcement services. The company also operates a homeland-security
division that provides border security, information analysis, and
emergency response for situations involving chemical agents, biological
warfare, and weapons of mass destruction. US government and public
agencies, including the Internal Revenue Service, the National
Aeronautics and Space Administration (NASA), the Department of Energy,
and the US Army, are paying clients.
The late George R Wackenhut, a former US Federal Bureau of
Investigation (FBI) agent, built the Wackenhut Corp into an
international security firm that promoted the use of private guards at
prisons, airports and nuclear power plants. From the McCarthy era on,
when a communist could be found hiding under almost every bed in the
United States, the country's appetite for private security escalated
into hysteria. George Wackenhut cashed in by persuading thousands of
communities and government agencies to put private guards in public
jobs, a move long resisted in vain by law-enforcement officials.
Started in 1954 as a three-man detective agency in Miami, the
struggling company turned to providing guard services to stay afloat
and later earned contracts with Lockheed Martin and the Kennedy Space
Center in Florida to protect classified projects from communist spies.
To impress potential clients, Wackenhut dressed his guards in helmets
and paratrooper boots, and he recruited former members of the Central
Intelligence Agency (CIA), the FBI and elite military forces to join
management and the company's board. Over the next four decades,
Wackenhut personnel guarded corporate buildings during labor strikes,
managed security for airlines at nearly 90 airports, and supplemented
municipal services such as fire fighting and emergency medical services
in several small communities. Its guards patrolled the Atomic Energy
Commission's nuclear test site in Nevada and even a handful of US
embassies.
The company's expansion into prison security and other correctional
operations in the 1980s became its most profitable move. It was one of
the first private security firms hired by the Federal Bureau of Prisons
and has since received federal contracts from the US Marshals Service
and the immigration and customs enforcement division of the Department
of Homeland Security. The privatization of prisons has had its critics
and Wackenhut's guards have been accused of abusing inmates in Florida,
Texas and Louisiana. The Wackenhut Correction Corp, the company's
prisons subsidiary, now manages more than 40,000 prison beds, mostly in
the United States, the United Kingdom, Australia and New Zealand.
According to a head count taken in the middle of 2002, the 50 US
states, the District of Columbia and the federal government held
1,355,748 prisoners (two-thirds of the total incarcerated population),
and local municipal and county jails held 665,475 inmates, with a total
of more than 2 million inmates. US jails held one of every 142 US
residents. Males were incarcerated at the rate of 1,309 inmates per
100,000 men, while the female incarceration rate was 113 per 100,000
female residents. Of the 1,200,203 state prisoners, 3,055 were younger
than 18 years of age. In addition, adult jails held 7,248 inmates under
18. As of June 30, 2002, state and federal correctional authorities
held 88,776 non-citizens, a 1% increase from the 87,917 held a year
earlier. Sixty-two percent were held in state prisons and 38% in
federal institutions. Privately operated prisons held 86,626 inmates.
By comparison, the US has 983,000 hospital beds, less than half of the
number of prison beds. That is a failed-state syndrome if there were
ever one.
As his company grew, Wackenhut recruited prominent directors such as
Clarence M Kelley, former head of the FBI; James J Rowley, former
director of the US Secret Service; and Frank C Carlucci, former US
defense secretary and former CIA deputy director. Before president
Ronald Reagan appointed him director of central intelligence, William J
Casey was Wackenhut's outside legal counsel. Such connections fueled
speculation that the company was a front for the CIA, which Wackenhut
denied.
Wackenhut, outspoken in his conservative politics, was occasionally
seen as overly zealous in his investigative assignments. In 1967, when
governor Claude R Kirk Jr of Florida appointed him chief of a private
police force to investigate organized crime, Wackenhut was criticized
for saying publicly that he and his officers would not limit themselves
to suspected criminals but would "investigate everyone and anyone who
needs investigating". The police force was short-lived, but the
company's tactics created a dispute again in 1991, when a congressional
inquiry found that it had spied on an environmental advocate by
installing miniature cameras in his hotel rooms and illegally taking
documents from his home in his absence.
Kroll is another major private security company. Its experts in
security, protection, engineering, business continuity and emergency
management help clients prevent, prepare for and respond to the many
threats they face at home and abroad that the state fails to provide.
Kroll's approaches are designed to respond quickly to changing threat
conditions and ensure operational continuity in the wake of a crisis.
Global threats are forcing companies to take a harder look at their
security programs. From assessment to implementation, clients are told
they can benefit from Kroll's seamless integration of services,
resulting in a more efficient, cost-effective security program, albeit
at times outside the law even if technically not illegal. Kroll experts
develop proactive, tiered approaches that can respond quickly to
changing threat conditions and help ensure operational continuity in
the wake of a crisis. Private security programs can be free of
civil-rights restraints. Kroll's 2003 sales were $485.5 million, with
year-on-year sales growth of 67.9%. Last May 18, Kroll Inc and Marsh
and McLennan Companies (MMC), the insurance broker now under
investigation, announced that they had entered into a merger agreement
under which MMC would acquire Kroll Inc in a $1.9 billion cash
transaction. In October, New York Attorney General Elliot Spitzer sued
Marsh & McLennan, the world's largest insurance broker, accusing it
of rigging bids and fixing prices while steering business to insurers
that paid the highest placement fees. In January, Marsh agreed to pay
$850 million to settle the suit, in line with placement fees it
collected in 2003, and agreed to change its business practices. Marsh
took a pretax charge of $618 million in the fourth quarter for the
settlement, in addition to a $232 million charge taken in the third
quarter. The New York-based company reported a 2004 fourth-quarter loss
of $676 million, or $1.28 a share, compared with a profit of $375
million, or 69 cents a share, a year earlier. In essence, US taxpayers
paid for MMC settlement costs.
Washington Group International Inc, based in Boise, Idaho, with
approximately 27,000 employees at work in more than 40 US states and
more than 30 countries, provides professional, scientific, management,
and development services in more than two dozen major markets. Founded
in 1964 by Dennis R Washington in Missoula, Montana, the company rose
to the top of the civil-construction market in Montana, and expanded
into mining, industrial construction, and environmental clean-up work.
As his company grew into a major regional firm, Washington's vision for
the future continued to expand also, leading to a series of
acquisitions that produced the international powerhouse the company is
today. In 1993, Washington Construction Co expanded its heavy
civil-construction operation when it merged with Kasler Corp, a
California-based firm with large-scale operations in heavy civil
construction. In 1996, Washington Construction acquired Morrison
Knudsen, gaining an 84-year heritage of mining, engineering and
construction globally. With the acquisition, the company had
capabilities and services that reached across five markets:
infrastructure, mining, industrial/process, energy and environment, and
power. In 1999, the company acquired the government-services operations
of Westinghouse Electric Co, becoming a science and technology services
leader. In 2000, the company expanded its market leadership by
acquiring Raytheon Engineers and Constructors to produce one of the
largest companies in the industry.
Today, Washington Group holds leading positions in six top markets and
a service offering that spans the entire range of its clients' needs,
unifying a vision that has been 10 years in the making. Being the
undisputed leader in the destruction of US stockpiles of chemical
weapons, Washington Group has contracts with the US government worth
more than $4.2 billion to design, build, operate, and close
chemical-weapons destruction plants at four sites in the United States.
Washington Group's Westinghouse Savannah River Co has operated since
1989 the 803-square-kilometer Savannah River Site (SRS) for the US
Department of Energy (DOE). The site is home to the Defense Waste
Processing Facility, the largest high-level radioactive-liquid
stabilization plant in the world. The site's approximately 9,000
employees are engaged in environmental remediation and maintenance of
the nation's nuclear stockpile. Washington Group's involvement at SRS
is ever changing from production of weapons-grade plutonium and tritium
during the Cold War to cleanup and disposal today. The SRS continues to
meet the changing needs of the DOE.
Cold War nuclear deterrence was based on the doctrine of mutually
assured destruction (MAD) with long-range delivery systems armed with
independently targetable re-entry warheads. The SRS in South Carolina
was constructed in the early stages of the Cold War. The site's main
purpose was to produce basic materials used in the fabrication of
nuclear weapons, primarily tritium and plutonium-239. The five reactors
built at the site produced weapons-grade nuclear materials that were
used in weaponry as well as plutonium-238 for power sources for NASA
deep-space missions. The SRS has operated for almost half a century.
When Westinghouse Savannah River Co took over the site in 1989, its
task was to re-engineer and upgrade three of the five 1950s-era nuclear
reactors that produced plutonium and tritium.
By the end of the decade the global balance of power had shifted. With
the end of the Cold War, and the dissolution of the Soviet Union, the
role of the Savannah River Site and other DOE defense-related
facilities changed.
Washington Group's history at the SRS is one of dealing with the
changing needs of the DOE. It is a large and complex site and one of
the many challenges the company tackles is how to adapt to new DOE
missions and changing national priorities. As a result of privatization
of DOE functions, private profit became a legitimate factor in the
deliberation in the nation's nuclear policy.
With the passage of arms-reduction treaties, the need for plutonium and
tritium declined. The SRS mission shifted from nuclear armament to
disarmament in areas such as groundwater remediation, cleaning up
inactive waste sites, and waste management, pollution that had been
part of the armament process. By the middle of the 1980s, construction
was started on a major facility that would immobilize high-level
radioactive waste and convert it into a durable glass form through a
process called vitrification. The Defense Waste Processing Facility
(DWPF) would become the world's largest system for stabilizing
radioactive waste in glass.
The terrorist attacks of September 11, 2001, heightened the United
States' awareness of the wide-ranging consequences of such attacks. To
reduce America's vulnerability to terrorism and other disasters,
President Bush issued the National Strategy for Homeland Security
(NSHS) to protect public health and safety and key assets vital to US
government, economy and morale. Its mission is twofold: 1) to mobilize
the entire nation in a concerted effort to protect its homeland from
terrorists and 2) to ensure a high level of security in a free and
ever-changing society.
Washington Group International sees itself playing a crucial role in
homeland security, helping to prevent, protect, and prepare for
catastrophic threats to the US as well as developing recovery
techniques should such attacks occur. These efforts are focused on
protecting military bases, both at home and abroad, securing critical
infrastructure against modern threats, such as dirty bombs, by
utilizing innovative detection and mitigation systems. Washington Group
provides a wide range of engineering, construction, and threat-analysis
services to government customers. These specialized services include:
Real-time threat simulation; security vulnerability analysis and
mitigation; emergency and crisis response; security-related technology
integration and deployment; hazard assessment; and threat and
consequence assessment.
Washington Group International claimed a leading role in ridding the US
and the world of weapons of mass destruction (WMD) when operations
began last August 9 at the Anniston Chemical Agent Disposal Facility
(ANCDF) in Alabama. Over the next seven years, Washington
Demilitarization Co and its subsidiary, Westinghouse Anniston, is
scheduled to destroy hundreds of thousands of chemical weapons stored
at the Anniston Army Depot.
In the former Soviet Union (FSU), Lugar-Nunn legislation is providing
funding to help former Soviet states dismantle their arsenals of WMD.
Washington Group International is the first foreign organization
successfully to license and design, construct and operate a Cooperative
Threat Reduction (CTR) facility in the FSU. Washington Group was
awarded six contracts by the US Defense Department's Defense Threat
Reduction Agency (DTRA) to build a Neutralization and Dismantling
Facility (NDF) in Dniepropetrovsk, Ukraine, where the company
disassembled, eliminated, disposed and salvaged SS-19 missiles.
After the collapse of the Soviet Union, Ukraine, a country of 52
million people, inherited the world's third-largest nuclear arsenal.
There were more than 180 intercontinental ballistic missiles (ICBMs)
with more than 1,200 warheads on Ukrainian territory. The stockpile
consisted of 133 SS-19s and 46 SS-24s armed with nuclear warheads.
There were an additional 14 SS-24s present in Ukraine but not deployed
with warheads. Ukraine also inherited several dozen bombers with
nuclear capabilities that were armed with approximately 600
air-launched bombs and more gravity bombs. As many as 3,000 tactical
weapons rounded out the arsenal that totaled about 5,000 strategic and
tactical weapons. A trilateral agreement signed in January 1994 by the
US, Russia and Ukraine that would send the nuclear warheads back to
Russia was the first step in making Ukraine a nuclear-free nation.
Washington Group went to Ukraine in 1994 in a partnership with Thiokol,
a rocket-motor maker. Thiokol needed a company with construction and
engineering experience for work in the FSU. The US partners won the
contract that turned into a disassembly and elimination project with
the Defense Nuclear Agency, later renamed the Defense Threat Reduction
Agency. From 1994 through 2003 the Department of Defense awarded
Washington Group a series of contracts to disassemble, dispose,
eliminate, salvage and store Soviet ICBMs for the DTRA. An early
contract called for the design, construction management and operation
of a 2694-square-meter Neutralization and Dismantling Facility (NDF) in
the southern oblast of Dniepropetrovsk, a Soviet
industrial/technology center that had produced trucks from 1944 until
May of 1951, when production switched to ballistic missiles. During the
final stages of the Cold War, Leonid Kuchma directed operations at the
Dniepropetrovsk plant that produced missiles, space-launch vehicles,
satellites and rocket engines. In the waning years of the Soviet
regime, maintenance on the facility diminished as the Soviet economy
collapsed. After the dissolution of the USSR, Kuchma became Ukraine's
prime minister (1992-93) and then its second president in July 1994. He
remained in power until January 23, 2005, when his hand-picked
successor, Viktor Yanukovych, lost the presidential election to Viktor
Yushchenko.
Guardsmark is the world's largest employer of former FBI agents and
also one of the largest security firms in the United States. Guardsmark
operates in some 400 cities in North America, where it provides
security services to the financial, utility, transportation, and
health-care industries. The company offers security guards, private
investigation, and drug-testing services. It consults with architects
and builders to design security programs. Guardsmark also conducts
background checks (employment, education, and criminal history) and
provides outsourcing services (Peoplemark). Chairman and president Ira
Lipman owns the company, which he founded in 1963.
Allied-Barton Security Services, formerly Allied Security, is one of
the largest private security firms in the US. The company serves more
than 2,100 clients through more than 60 offices in 37 states. The
company primarily provides security guards and staffing services for
shopping malls, office buildings, hospitals, corporate complexes, and
universities, but also offers 24-hour alarm monitoring, closed-circuit
television systems, access-control systems, and burglar- and fire-alarm
systems. In addition, Allied Security provides consulting services and
facility assessment. The company, which is owned by MacAndrews and
Forbes Holdings, has acquired and merged with Barton Protection
Services. Sales in 2003 were $550 million, year-on-year sales growth
was 10%, and it had 23,000 employees, boasting year-on-year employee
growth of 21.1%.
Inter-Con Security Systems, one of the largest private security
consulting firms in the US, provides custom-designed security programs
for commercial, governmental, and industrial clients in 25 countries on
four continents. Its services include security consulting, protection,
investigations, and training. It also provides security-guard and
patrol services. Inter-Con's clients have included NASA, the Academy
Awards, and the US government. The company, founded in 1973, is owned
by chief executive officer Rick Hernandez and the Hernandez family.
Sales in 2003 were $1 billion, and the company had 25,000 employees.
Run by former US Secret Service agents, Vance International, a part of
SPX's Security and Investigations Unit, offers executive protection,
uniformed guards, investigations and training. It also provides asset
protection and temporary labor for companies during strikes or natural
disasters. Serving corporations and government agencies, as well as the
occasional celebrity, Vance International has been called the
"Rolls-Royce" of security firms; clients have included Bill Gates,
Nelson Mandela and Arnold Schwarzenegger. President and chief executive
officer Chuck Vance founded the firm in 1984, acquired by SPX in 2002.
Security on the cheap
By September 2001 there were an estimated 1 million to 2 million
workers in some 13,000 private security companies in the US, and some
say there are now twice as many private security workers as police
officers. The number of workers in the industry grew nearly 20% in the
last decade, and according to the Bureau of Labor Statistics, it will
continue to increase as companies beef up security to allay fears of
crime, vandalism and terrorism.
These guards, however, are not police officers. Instead, they are
uniformed watchmen, usually unarmed, who patrol airports, shopping
malls, private businesses and college campuses. As companies downsize,
they often have their security personnel - typically provided by
third-party contractors - perform two jobs at once. These "guards" also
double as receptionists or customer service workers. Even the
government, in efforts to cut costs, sometimes subcontracts security in
prisons and federal buildings to private security companies.
And of course, these companies have been used to break union picket
lines and defend strikebreakers. Public-sector unions are also keeping
a wary eye on the small but growing trend of private security guards
replacing unionized public employees. Unlike their public-sector or
in-house counterparts, these private security guards are not highly
trained or well paid.
And while many in the security industry, including the managers of some
security companies, are pushing for national standards concerning
training and skill level, the industry does not pay enough to attract
and maintain qualified personnel. Richard Marinaro, Long Island
director of Boston-based Unico Security Services, told Newsday in 1998
that the security companies "can't get people at these wages, and we're
in competition with the McDonald's and the Wendy's [fast-food chains]
of the world". Yet the jobs that these guards are asked to do - working
eight-hour shifts without a lunch break, showing restraint and judgment
when dealing with the general public, serving as witnesses in court -
require more skill, training, and dedication than working in fast food.
Stories of shoddy work and/or theft by the security guards who are
supposed to protect people and property are surprisingly commonplace
among the companies that specialize in providing private security in
the US. For example, workers for Argenbright, a company that provides
workers for security checkpoints in airports, were involved in four
airport security breaches in less than a year in 1997-98, as well as
one that required an evacuation of the United Airlines terminal at
Chicago's O'Hare Airport in 1999. In April 2000, federal prosecutors
also found that Argenbright officials at Philadelphia International
Airport routinely falsified records, hired convicted felons, and
provided low-paid employees with answers to federally required tests
for baggage screeners.
One trend that has coincided with the increase in incidents involving
private security and their low wages is the industry's drift toward
consolidation. Last August, Pinkerton, a subsidiary of Sweden-based
Securitas, merged with Burns International Corp, another industry
leader, to create a private security giant with more than 600 offices
internationally and annual revenue of more than $2.5 billion. Two
Pennsylvania companies, Allied Security and SpectaGuard, also merged in
2000, making the company the largest independently held security
company in the country and giving it business in more than 250 cities
across the US.
With consolidation has come corporatization of the industry, something
that in the eyes of some industry insiders has led industry leaders to
sacrifice quality service for an image that sells. "Pinkerton sold out
to a low-end, minimum-wage type of service," said Roger Schmedlen,
president of Loss Prevention Concepts Ltd, a Michigan-based security
consulting agency, as he described Pinkerton's entry into lower-level
watchman service in the early 1980s. "They put out all of these slick
brochures and took on a national advertising campaign, and it changed
the industry. They have some great pictures of guys that look like
Superman, but government studies show that the typical security guard
doesn't have much more than an eighth-grade education, and is elderly."
But Pinkerton, and most other companies, also offer more "high end"
security guards - ones who are better trained, more skilled, and better
paid. "There are some really good guards out there," Schmedlen noted.
"But a lot of these companies just go for the low bid and take it."
Ultimately, these companies, which have reaped the benefits of
exploding demand for security guards in the US, have skimped on wages
whenever possible to maximize profit. "They're profit-making
enterprises, and they have stockholders and shareholders," explained
one industry observer. "In any kind of safety operation, the bulk of
the expense goes towards personnel compensation. So if you want to try
to make a profit, the first thing you make cuts in are wages and
benefits."
With its low wages, low standards, and poor working conditions, the
private-security industry is one that, on the surface, seems ripe for
unionization. But a provision of the National Labor Relations Act
stipulates: "No labor organization shall be certified as the
representative of employees in a bargaining unit of guards if such
organization admits to membership, or is affiliated directly or
indirectly with an organization which admits to membership, employees
other than guards" (source: Section 159, Title 29 of the US Labor
Code). This provision, known more commonly as the "Guard Law", gives
management the right to refuse workers' petitions to join a union such
as the Teamsters, the Service Employees International Union (SEIU), or
any other international union that has members outside of the security
sector. While it was originally written to prevent potential conflicts
of interest in labor disputes (if United Auto Workers guards were
assigned to defend against a UAW plant strike, for example), it also
serves to undermine efforts by unions to gain an organizing foothold in
the industry.
There is, however, a loophole that unions can use to gain recognition.
Management can voluntarily choose to recognize guards as part of a
larger union, as some have in card-check elections. Argenbright airport
workers in Los Angeles and San Francisco were able to do this when they
voted to join the SEIU. Mitigating circumstances, such as public
pressure or the fact that many companies prefer to deal with a union
instead of individual employees, have helped international unions gain
recognition from some of these security companies. And while other
security guards have the option of joining other small, unaffiliated
unions that represent only security personnel, still less than 10% of
the US industry is organized.
As with many of the increasing number of low-paying service jobs that
have sprung up in the past decade, the growing ranks of private
security guards represent another challenge for organized labor. If
they are going to maintain their foothold among the blue-collar
workforce, unions need to adapt and adjust to the realities of
exploitative industries that will continue to sacrifice both quality
service and decent wages until their workers gain a decent voice on the
job.
The employees of the private security sector, in essence a private
army, are greater in number than the soldiers in the US Army. This
private army thrives on social instability and state failure. These
private security companies have no financial incentive to promote peace
and stability. The dependence of the state on their contracted service
gives them an influential voice in formulating state policies. Security
threat is big business and any reduction of threats in fact threatens
the economy.
Markets provide a variety of incentives to producers, their customers,
and local communities to guard against a wide range of risks, including
the possibility of terrorism. Private producers of goods and services
generally will benefit from safe operating practices (including
physical security) and the purchase of insurance to help limit any
financial losses. But the incentives for private businesses to reduce
their vulnerability to attack, and the potential losses for those who
would be affected, may be inadequate when the private costs of the
threat of terrorism are lower than the social costs, or equivalently,
when the private benefits from security measures are less than the
social benefits.
Private costs would be closely associated with damages to production
and distribution facilities and the harm to industry workers, as well
as the potential loss of business. But the total social costs could go
further and include the harm or loss of life to individuals such as the
neighbors of a targeted facility or the consumers of a tainted product,
damage to the local environment, and negative effects on other
businesses dependent on the targeted industry. If the product of the
targeted industry became a potential weapon in attacks elsewhere, the
social costs could be broader still. For example, stolen chemicals
could be used to attack an office building. If the disparity between
private costs and social costs is significant, the result is that
private firms have insufficient incentive to meet social objectives.
Many of the US government programs that existed before September 11 are
intended to bring private and social costs into line. Many firms had
long been subject to extensive government intervention because of the
dangers that those industries' operations or products can pose to
public safety, environmental quality, and local economies.
Existing government programs provide a starting point for examining
possible new efforts. Those programs may be adequate to prompt
businesses to address much or all of the increased terrorist threat.
But if private efforts are inadequate, policy options for prompting
additional efforts will probably build on the incentives generated by
existing requirements. Cost-effective policies for enhancing homeland
security may involve expanding some programs that have non-security
goals while reducing others. For example, programs that were intended
primarily to help protect the public from relatively common threats,
such as industrial accidents or food contamination, could be expanded
to help address the terrorist threat. But programs that were intended
to disseminate information on critical industries, such as the
production and storage capacities of hazardous facilities, might need
to be curtailed to keep that information out of the hands of
terrorists.
If a chemical-production facility were subject to an attack, for
example, the ensuing fire or explosion could expose the surrounding
community to dangerous toxins. That added exposure would represent a
social cost that the private firm would not face - especially if the
damage exceeded the limits of the owner's insurance coverage and other
financial resources. As a result, the owner would have less incentive
than otherwise to guard against such attacks, scale back operations, or
relocate. Current government programs affecting the safety of
chemical-plant operations and supporting local emergency preparations
are a response to that social cost and also contribute to homeland
security. However, the increased awareness of the terrorist threat
since September 11, if not the threat itself, also may indicate a need
to step up security efforts since the social benefits of spending on
security have increased.
The type of intervention that would force industry to internalize the
costs of security and for which it would bear the immediate costs would
include requirements to take preventive measures, assessment of
penalties for failing to take certain actions, or imposition of taxes
on certain activities or products.
The type of intervention that would have the government socialize the
cost - so that everyone paid for the enhanced security - would include
new programs that rewarded industry for taking measures to protect
vulnerable facilities or make those facilities less dangerous, for
example, by supporting the adoption of safer production processes or
the use of safer chemicals. Alternatively, rather than force or pay
industry to make certain changes, new programs could help inform nearby
residents of the dangers of an attack or inform industry of currently
available options for reducing its vulnerabilities.
The use of mercenaries in war
The Guardian reported that with the casualty toll ticking ever upward
and troops stretched thin on the ground in Iraq and Afghanistan, the
Bush administration is looking to mercenaries to help control Iraq.
These soldiers-for-hire are veterans of some of the most repressive
military forces in the world, including that of the former Chilean
dictator Augusto Pinochet and South Africa's apartheid regime. In
February 2003, Blackwater USA, a North Carolina-based Pentagon
contractor, began hiring former combat personnel in Chile, offering
them up to $4,000 a month to guard oil wells in Iraq. The company flew
the first batch of 60 former commandos to a training camp in North
Carolina. These recruits will eventually wind up in Iraq where they
will spend six months to a year.
"We scour the ends of the Earth to find professionals - the Chilean
commandos are very, very professional and they fit within the
Blackwater system," Gary Jackson, the president of Blackwater USA, told
the Guardian early last year. While Blackwater USA is not nearly as
well known as Halliburton or Bechtel - two mega-corporations making a
killing off the reconstruction of Iraq - it nevertheless is doing quite
well financially thanks to the White House's "war on terror". The
company specializes in firearms, tactics and security training, and in
October 2003, according to Mother Jones magazine, the company won a
$35.7 million contract to train more than 10,000 sailors from Virginia,
Texas and California each year in "force protection".
Business has been booming for Blackwater, which now owns, as its press
release boasts, "the largest privately owned firearms training facility
in the nation". In an interview with the Guardian, Jackson said: "We
have grown 300% over each of the past three years [before March 2004]
and we are small compared to the big ones. We have a very small niche
market - we work towards putting out the cream of the crop, the best."
The practice of using mercenaries to fight wars is hardly new, but it
has become increasingly popular in recent years. During the first Gulf
War (1990-91), one out of every 50 soldiers on the battlefield was a
mercenary. That number climbed to one in 10 during the Bosnian conflict
(1996). Currently there are thousands of Bosnian, Filipino and US
soldiers under contract with private companies serving in Iraq. Their
duties have ranged from airport security to protecting Paul Bremer, the
former head of the Coalition Provisional Authority.
Apart from Chile, the other popular source for military recruits is
South Africa. The United Nations recently reported that South Africa
"is already among the top three suppliers of personnel for private
military companies, along with the UK and the US". There are more than
1,500 South Africans in Iraq today, most of whom are former members of
the South African Defense Force and South African police.
According to the Cape Times, among the South African companies under
contract with the Pentagon are Meteoric Tactical Solutions, which "is
providing protection and is also training new Iraqi police and security
units", and Erinys, a joint South African-British company, which "has
received a multimillion-dollar contract to protect Iraq's oil
industry," the Cape Times reported early last year.
The recruitment of its citizens, however, leaves the Chilean and South
African governments less than happy. The Regulation of Foreign Military
Assistance Act prohibits South African citizens from direct
participation as a combatant in armed conflict for private gain.
Michelle Bachelet, Chile's former defense minister, ordered an
investigation into whether such recruitment was legal under Chilean
laws. Bachelet also was troubled by stories that soldiers on active
duty were leaving the company to sign up as mercenaries.
It is also only a matter of time before US soldiers grow unhappy with
the presence of mercenaries in their midst. The high salaries and
shorter terms of employment offered to mercenaries will inevitably make
a serious dent on the military's budget. As Blackwater's Jackson
acknowledged in the Guardian, "If they are going to outsource tasks
that were once held by active-duty military and are now using private
contractors, those guys [on active duty] are looking and asking: Where
is the money?"
Raenette Taljaard, a member of the South African parliament, has
describes the ubiquitous reach of this "booming cottage industry" of
private security companies: "In addition to becoming an integral part
of the machinery of war, they are emerging as cogs in the
infrastructure of peace. US-allied military officials and civilians in
Iraq and Afghanistan are quickly becoming familiar with the 'brand
services' provided by companies." In the era of neo-liberal
globalization, war has become just another industry to be outsourced.
Next: Lessons
of the Thirty Years' War for the "war on terrorism" |
|
|
|
|