|
Big
money and the Corn Laws
By
Henry C K Liu
This article appeared in Asia Times
Online on May 1, 2002
Trade is never politically neutral. A look at the politics of trade in
19th-century industrial England, where the modern world trade started,
can yield some insight on the politics currently surrounding
globalization and its institutional agents: the World Trade
Organization and the International Monetary Fund. Since trade and
foreign exchange are inseparable, the functions of the WTO are
similarly inseparable from those of the IMF.
Some 170 years ago, the short, three-day Paris July Revolution
of 1830 rose out of a coalition of the upper bourgeoisie, workers,
students and the intelligentsia in opposition to Charles X's
reactionary
policies against, and institutional repression of, the progressive
forces that had their roots in the French Revolution, in the decade
after the defeat of Napoleon. French class conflict had vented itself
through violent revolution because absolute monarchy had been
unchallenged until the revolution, as distinct from the evolution of
constitutional monarchy in Britain. The French bourgeoisie had no
choice but to smash absolutism with the violent passion of the lower
classes. Even after the revolution, bourgeois hegemony remained
precarious in France because of the residual imprint of the feudal
political culture of the ancien regime,
despite wholesale cultural cleansing by the radical populist Hebertists
in their de-Christianization movement and indiscriminate political
cleansing by the Reign of Terror.
The reformist bourgeoisie for limited adjustments toward constitutional
monarchy, meritocracy, free enterprise, still narrowly property-based
laws and state institutions was overtaken by the peasant and plebeian
explosion that it had neither wanted nor led. But once the populist
movement was subdued, the bourgeoisie quite naturally became the ruling
class because of its wealth and dominance of the economy.
The absolutist structure now lay in ruins, and the aristocracy lost its
feudal privileges. The market economy could spread through all the
breaches opened in the collapsed old feudal order, and the bourgeoisie
was the obvious class to profit from it, through the power of money, as
opposed to the ancient regime
role of money as merely an instrument of established political power.
The aristocracy retained some residual wealth through its
reconciliation with the bourgeoisie in the united front of the property
owners against the plebeians. But the future roles of the heirs of the
old nobles were not as feudal lords but as large capitalist landowners
and as arbitrageurs of social manners eagerly aped by the merchant
class.
It is a misleading oversimplification to interpret
contemporary social and political struggles in capitalist countries as
exclusively based on the struggle of the two fundamental classes, the
bourgeoisie and proletariat. Society is infinitely more complex.
Repeatedly, absolutism rallied the plebeians against the nobility or
bourgeoisie, or the bourgeoisie against the nobility, or the nobility
rallied the plebeians against absolutism allied to the bourgeoisie.
This complexity has not diminished in modern times. Absolutism belongs
now to history, but sovereignty is alive and well.
The post-revolution French bourgeoisie gained economic
dominance yet politically failed to achieve direct control of the state
apparatus. Modern capitalism suffered the same fate in many countries.
On the coup of 18th Brumiare (November 8-9, 1799) that established the
Consulate under Napoleon, Karl Marx insightfully described the
historical political immaturity of the bourgeoisie in France; that the
French Revolution, with its focus on dismantling all local,
territorial, urban, provincial and independent powers in order to
create the bourgeois unity of the nation, was bound to develop what the
absolute monarchy had begun - centralization, and the extent, the
attributes and the agents of governmental authority. It was then left
to Napoleon to perfect this state machinery.
Neo-liberal globalization faces the same fate. The
centralization tendencies of the WTO and IMF run counter to those of
national sovereignty.
Earnst Cassirer, in the chapter on Hegel in his The Myth of the
State,
wrote: "Hegelianism has had to pay the penalty of its triumph." It is
an observation very applicable to Statism. The state apparatus of the
New Deal, as constructed under US president Franklin D Roosevelt,
evolved naturally into the postwar military-industrial complex so loved
by the right wing. Hans Morganthal (Politics Among Nations)
developed the theme that US postwar foreign policy was "imperialistic"
in the
non-pejorative sense of the word, because it was expansionist and
empire-building for the postwar Pax Americana. Of course, both an
interventionist government and a military-industrial complex are
necessary for an "imperialistic" foreign policy.
Thus the revolutionary movement to establish a democratic
republic was betrayed in 1830 by the victorious bourgeoisie who turned
against populist democracy to prefer a constitutional monarchy with a
puppet king, in the person of Louis-Philippe, endorsed by Lafayette of
revolutionary pedigree who had adopted a conservative outlook, despite
having been imprisoned by Austria as an anti-monarchist until he was
liberated by Napoleon.
Yet the betrayal of a revolution of working-class insurrection
did not dampen radical industrialist leaders in England in their belief
that political violence by workers, or the threat of it, might be
useful to capitalist causes. The old Tory regime of England began to
face challenge by a young radical group sensitive to the needs of new
British industrial business interests under the then revolutionary
doctrine of liberalism. To protect themselves from the landed
aristocrats and the old, biased "watch" system, these radical liberals
even introduced a politically neutral professional police in London,
called "bobbies", after Robert Peel, scion of the leading new cotton
manufacturer family who pushed the idea.
These industrialist radicals allowed the first legal crack for
unionism and liberalized the old Navigation Act, permitting British
colonies to trade with nations other than Britain. They also legalized
the emigration of skilled workers and the export of British
manufacturing machines. They also further advanced the concept of a
secular state responsive to the laws of economics rather than divine
right of the sovereign and hierarchical feudalism.
But they could not reform parliament, nor the Corn Law of 1815
which protected the interests (rent rolls) of the landed gentry who
controlled parliament, led by the ultra-conservative Duke of
Wellington, victor at Waterloo over Napoleon. Characteristically,
parliamentary democracy stood in the path of socio-economic progress.
The 1832 Reform Bill was finally passed under threats of
further popular uprising, after incited mobs gained control of Bristol,
stormed the jail at Darby and burned Nottingham castle. The Bill
heralded the political victory of the British bourgeoisie who stood for
industrialization and trade. The liberal Tories eventually became the
Liberals and the Tory/Whig coalition became the Conservatives. To
deflect attacks on traditional economic privileges, the Conservatives
became champions of early workers rights in the new industries and
mines, with a devious objective of financially ruining the new
entrepreneurs. The Factory Act of 1833, instigated by Robert Owen,
forbade child labor (below nine years old) in textile mills, a historic
first. But child labor was allowed to continue on the farms as a benign
feudal tradition. The Mining Act of 1842 regulated mine employment,
forbidding below-ground work the highest paid) for women, and children
under 10. The Ten-Hour Act of 1847, passed by the Conservatives in
parliament, was attacked by industrialists as "a delusion practiced on
the working class", and directly contradictory to the scientific
principles of laissez-faire economics.
The Liberals formed an Anti-Corn Law League (ACLL) in 1838.
The ACLL components included wage earners who wanted low food prices,
and industrialists who wanted low wages based on low food costs. The
Corn Law defenders cited food independence, national security
arguments, and the need to preserve English natural aristocracy social
values. But the bottom line was a struggle between new industrialists
with support of their workers on one side (oppressed as workers were,
and the latent agitation that led to the Revolutions of 1848 and the
Communist Manifesto notwithstanding) and the traditional landed-gentry
establishment power on the other.
The ACLL, based in Manchester, richly funded by both big
industries and newly organized wage earners, not unlike many
"neo-liberal" think tanks of today, launched a relentless campaign of
lecture tours, newspaper articles, polemical pamphlets, political teas,
torchlight parades and mass meetings, ironically not unlike the
anti-globalization movement that culminated in Seattle in 1999. Thus
was born the Manchester School of Economics. Richard Cobden (1804-65),
a leading spokesman for the Manchester School of Free Trade, finally
won over Sir Robert Peel (second ministry 1841-46), and the Corn Law
was repealed in 1846, two years before the revolutions of 1848, along
with virtual abandonment of custom duties and the introduction of the
income tax to fill the revenue gap. After 1849, Cobden concerned
himself chiefly with isolationist foreign policy, advocating
non-intervention in Europe and an end to imperial expansion. In 1859,
he negotiated the "Cobden Treaty" for reciprocal tariffs with France
under Napoleon III, the bourgeois emperor, putting the last nail in the
coffin of the anti-British Continental System imposed by Napoleon I,
the real emperor.
The original Corn Laws in 1360 were a set of regulations
restricting the export or import of grain to keep English grain prices
low. The purpose of the laws was to assure a stable and sufficient
supply of grain from domestic sources, yet allowing for import in time
of dearth. The Corn Law of 1815, in contrast, was designed to maintain
high farm prices and prevent an agricultural depression after the
Napoleonic Wars. Since its repeal in 1846, industrialism became the
governing force in England and free world trade its policy which
consolidated British control of the sea and the spread of official
British imperialism and its network of colonies that constituted the
British Empire. The Opium War took place in 1840.
This accelerated the growing consolidation of industrial
capitalism with colonialism under government protection. National
income for the imperialist countries grew, but a relatively small
portion of it went to domestic workers beyond subsistence. National
income between the home country and its colonies also polarized, as
between those nations with empires and those without, setting off a
race to acquire colonies even among minor European states such as
Holland and Belgium.
The accumulation of capital led to a need for a regime for the
export of capital in the overseas quest for lower raw material and
labor costs, as a way of keeping domestic labor costs low even as
general living standards rose. By 1839, British capital reached US$200
million in the US when US gross domestic product (GDP) was $610
million, total gross debt of the nation was only $3.5 million, customs
receipts totaled $23 million and tax receipt was a measly $2,553.
Workers were then told by the Manchester School intellectuals
that the income of workers is set by ineluctable laws of economic
science, that it is best and necessary to keep wages low and that the
way to a better life is to leave the working class and to ape the
employer, or eventually become a Labor Lord. This notwithstanding that
British society at that time provided not the slightest social mobility
dues to its rigid class structure institutionalized by exclusionary
social manners and elocution. Elaborate labor price theories were
concocted with circular data justifying the theories explaining
circularly that very same data as scientific truth, eventually leading
to the theory of non-acclerating inflation rate of unemployment
(NAIRU).
The reigning doctrine promoted the concept of a labor market.
Labor became a commodity, sold by the laborer and bought by the
employer in a fantasized free market, the ideal of which would be
totally free labor - at zero cost. Thus the English language is
insightful that "free" means both the ability to choose and a state of
worthlessness in a price regime. The hourly wage serves the employer
better than slavery. The employer is not even obliged to pay living
wages, as a slave owner had to bear the fixed cost of keeping slaves
alive and healthy for work. The labor market is described as being
governed by the laws of supply and demand. Low wages are the result of
market forces, not immorality on the part of greedy employers. And
surplus labor supply, like goods which are stored in warehouses, are to
be warehoused by poor relief. The common concept of a free market is
that it is a vehicle to realized the lowest price for the buyer rather
than the highest price for the seller, as in a cartel, which in modern
labor markets is called a labor strike. The New Poor Law of 1834
safeguarded the labor market for employers by making relief more
unpleasant than below living wage employment, supported with stern,
self-righteous precepts of the dismal science.
Two alternatives emerged as reaction: unionism and socialism
which asserts that goods are produced for use, not for sale. The term
"socialism" originated with the trade union movement founded by Robert
Owen around 1830. Socialism spread like wild flowers among the working
class after 1830. Industrial capitalism then countered it by gradually
tolerating unionism. In France, the socialist movement merged with
revolutionary republicanism. Robespierre was rehabilitated as a
people's hero despite that fact that the French Revolution aimed only
to establish private property rights against the hereditary privileges
of church, aristocracy and monarchy. Louis Blanc published his
Organization of Work in 1839. In England, Chartism, a working man's
reform movement, emerged during the decade of 1838-48 as a reaction to
the failure of the Reform Bill of 1832. It represented the first
attempt by the British working class to gain political power. All this
led to the revolutions of 1848, the suppression of which necessitated
unionism under industrial capitalism.
Obviously there were multidimensional motives behind the
Factory Acts; not the least was genuine social consciousness. Lord
Ashley, whose philosopher father was educated by John Locke, later the
seventh Earl of Shaftesbury, took the lead on publicizing the social
evils of rapid, unregulated industrialization. He even received support
from some humanitarian industrialists. Some early legislation adopted
the progressive practices of the more progressive and profitable firms
of
that period.
Yet the struggle between the landed gentry and the new
industrialists was the dominant play. The abolition of slavery in the
British Empire in 1833 cannot be fully understood outside of this
struggle. The 1835 Municipal Corporation Act, which modernized local
government by breaking up the traditional local oligarchies and
replaced them with uniform electoral and administrative machinery, was
another assault on the landed gentry. The reform of the Church of
England, particularly on unequal income between upper and lower clergy,
diluted the hold of the gentry on the Church. The shift of England
toward a secular state was tied up with this struggle.
The Tories, assaulted in their strongholds on local government
and the established Church, launched a counteroffensive into the
strongholds of the new liberal manufacturing class: factories and
mines. The struggle was couched in moral and scientific tones and often
not without sincerity and commitment. The aim of making
industrialization less profitable through increased labor costs was
undeniably part of the objectives of the Tories who saw the slowdown of
rapid industrialization via a dampening of profits as a strategy to
preserve their traditional privileges.
As it turned out, liberal labor practices and higher wages
provided the purchasing power to absorb the production increases of
industrialization. So the Tories inadvertently became the midwife to
economic democracy. Gladstone's second budget followed the Cobden
Treaty with France, a reciprocity agreement that called for another
increase in income tax to cover the shortfall of revenue for the
government.
Neo-liberals in the US promoted global free trade to dismantle
the hold of the sunset industries on US political power. Since the
beginning of globalization after the Cold War, no US president has come
from the Midwest industrial states or the Northeastern liberal states.
The collapse of the textile sector in the South, which had been moved a
generation earlier from the New England states, changed Democrat Party
politics. In retaliation, US labor targets the Third World, including
China, for labor practices of US transnationals. Just as industrialist
leaders in England believed that political violence by workers might be
useful to capitalist causes, neo-liberals look to labor unrest in China
after its WTO accession to serve capitalistic causes against Chinese
statism.
In the past two years, China has adopted a policy of rapidly
increasing wages (at the rate of 30 percent per year for three years)
in the state sector to stimulate needed domestic consumption and to
combat deflation. It reflects Chinese planners' increasing awareness of
the fundamental relationship between wages and economic growth. Income
is all, particularly under conditions of global overcapacity. It does
not mean, however, that the type of labor rights advocated by the
American Federation of Labor and Congress of Industrial Organizations
(AFL-CIO), which is politically based, is economically relevant.
Neo-liberal market fundamentalism in the 21st century creates
a political landscape no less complex than that surrounding the repeal
of the Corn Law in 1846. The Wall Street Journal celebrates mass
capitalism as the future world order. The membrane separating populist
socialism and mass capitalism may not be immune to osmosis.
|
|
|
|
|