|
Blaming 'undervalued'
yuan wins votes
By
Henry C K Liu
First appeared in Asia Times on
Line on February 26, 2004
With the 2004 US presidential
election drawing near, the trade deficit is again a campaign issue.
Proponents of globalization have long argued that the US current
account (trade) deficit is not a serious concern since it is being
financed by a capital account surplus supplied by America's trading
partners, providing ample debt financing for the dollar economy.
Imports from low-wage countries have kept the dollar inflation rate
low, with attendant benefits of low interest rates and high liquidity.
For more than a decade, the loss of US blue-collar manufacturing jobs
was accepted as what Federal Reserve Board chairman Alan Greenspan
called "creative destruction", a distortion of Joseph A Schumpeter's
concept of survival of the economically fittest through continuous
innovation.
Notwithstanding
that 2.1 million jobs have left the United States since President
George W Bush took office in January 2001, the dollar economy has not
lost manufacturing jobs; it merely relocated them overseas for more
productivity per unit of investment. US transnational companies are
still employing a growing global workforce for the benefit of US
consumers through cross-border wage arbitrage and dollar hegemony,
which permits a fiat currency of the world's most indebted nation to
retain the privileged status of reserve currency.
Thus when
US job growth slows, the stock market, which measures the global
performance of companies, rises. US labor unions have watched
helplessly the drastic drops in membership that translate into loss of
political leverage in shaping US economic policy. Greenspan told
Congress that "thinking" jobs are better than "doing" jobs. The United
States will keep high-paying jobs in financial services, management,
design, development, sales and distribution - and let the emerging
economies have the low-paying assembly-line jobs in factories owned by
US companies.
Even
small business, a key component in job creation, is increasingly taking
advantage of low-cost telecommunication and transportation to play the
wage-arbitrage game through cross-border outsourcing. Now that the
effects of cross-border wage arbitrage are hitting the high-tech
sector, laying off highly paid US high-tech workers and giving their
jobs to cheaper workers overseas, the political reverberations are
louder. In this jobless recovery, these better-educated workers have
the political clout to turn US policy toward protectionism.
The
impossible dream: Bringing back low-wage jobs
Yet the
structural characteristics of globalization make the prospect of
bringing low-paying manufacturing jobs back to high-wage locations an
impossible dream, unless US workers are prepared to work for
below-living wages and US industries are prepared to live with the
stricter US labor and environmental regulations. The dollar economy
grows at the expense of US domestic employment. The high yields on
workers' pension-fund investments are robbing the same workers of their
jobs.
This
structural crisis has been masked by the unprecedented expansion of US
consumer debts, which now exceed US$9 trillion, or 90 percent of gross
domestic product (GDP). This is collateralized by the wealth effect of
high returns on worker pension funds invested in the stock market and
the inflated value of their homes. Total credit-market debt for all
sectors is now 299 percent of GDP. In 1984, when consumer debt stood at
only 50 percent of GDP, it drove the market three years later, in 1987,
to a severe crash, which Greenspan bailed out with a flood of liquidity
that released the biggest financial bubble in history - it burst first
in Asia in 1997 and finally in the US in 2001.
Imports
from low-wage countries such as China are resold in the United States
at a greater profit margin for US importers than that enjoyed by
Chinese exporters. Thus a $2 toy leaving a US-owned factory in China is
a $3 shipment arriving at San Diego. By the time a US consumer buys it
for $10 at Wal-Mart, the US economy registers $10 in final sales, less
$3 import cost, for a $7 addition to the US GDP. This yields a ratio of
GDP gain to import value of two-and-a-third.
Chinese
GDP gain to export value ratio is zero if the $2 export price becomes
part of the US capital account surplus. If half of the $2 export price
is used for paying return to foreign capital, then the ratio is in fact
negative. The numbers for other product types vary, but the pattern is
similar. The $1.439 trillion of imports to the United States in 2002
were directly responsible for some $3.35 trillion of US GDP, almost 32
percent of its $10.45 trillion economy. That is why US policymakers
have no incentive to reduce the trade deficit. But during a
presidential campaign, blaming it on China's undervalued yuan gets
votes.
In 2003,
Chinese exports worldwide reached $430 billion, with imports of $410
billion, yielding a $20 billion surplus. The trade volume between China
and the US hit a historic high of $126 billion in 2003. China has
become America's third-largest trade partner. Chinese imports from the
US reached $34 billion, while exports to the US exceeded $92 billion.
China's worldwide trade surplus for 2003 was $25.5 billion, meaning
that more than half of the surplus from the United States went to cover
Chinese deficits with other trading partners.
Chinese
consumers can't afford their own exports
Since
Chinese export value constitutes only 20 percent of its final market
price, economies that buy from China enjoy a greater GDP growth from
trade ($2.15 trillion) than China does. Since China imports at full
market price with little markup, China does not enjoy any GDP add-on
from its imports. Fair trade between two economies with disparity in
wages and living standards then requires a trade surplus for the less
advanced economy.
If the
$430 billion of Chinese worldwide exports were consumed domestically at
their final market price, $2.15 trillion would be added to China's 2003
GDP of $1.41 trillion, more than doubling it. The higher the trade
surplus in China's favor, meaning more goods and services leaving China
than entering, the more serious is its adverse impact on China's GDP.
Chinese consumers cannot afford the products they produce for export -
not because Chinese workers are not productive, but because their wages
are too low, which ironically does not make Chinese products as
competitive overseas as can be because of high markup by foreign
importers.
Greater
profit margins enjoyed by the importing economy raise apparent
productivity because sales per employee increase from the factory floor
toward delivery to the consumer. Thus the productivity growth in the US
has been achieved by having cheap labor doing the producing overseas.
Also, the closer final assembly is to retail outlets, the higher its
apparent productivity. Through proximity to customers, sellers can gain
advantage in the assembly of imported major parts to respond to
changing customer orders. Thus US assemblers who outsource their parts
can win final sales away from offshore integrated manufacturers who
make the same parts and assemble them abroad. Japanese car makers have
learned this lesson and are now assembling parts made offshore in the
US for the US market.
In the
high-tech arena, time to market of design innovation is critical. By
deferring cost through the use of employee stock options, a local in
the importing country can use its high stock valuation driven by
creative accounting, and low production costs and low currency
valuation and interest rates in the exporter economy to raise low-cost
funds globally to subsidize production costs of the final product
further. The content of the products will increasingly come from
low-wage, low-margin exporting economies, and the outsourcing
assembler's manufacturing involvement may be little beyond snapping
outsourced parts in place, advertised ad nauseam as a US brand. Dell is
a classic example, as is Disney's licensing empire of made-in-China
toys.
Highly
indebted emerging market economies, through the undervaluation of their
currencies to subsidize exports, ironically make dollar debts more
expensive to repay in local currency terms. The moderating impact on US
price inflation also amplifies the upward trend of the trade-weighted
dollar index despite persistent US expansion of dollar monetary
aggregates, also known as money printing. Adjusting for this
debt-driven increase in the value of the dollar, import volume into the
US grew with the expansion of dollar monetary aggregates, around 15
percent annually for most of the 1990s. The US enjoyed a booming
economy when the exchange value of the dollar was rising, at a time
when interest rates in the US were higher than those in its creditor
nations.
Rising US
interest rates prolonged US boom
This led
to the odd effect that rising US interest rates actually prolonged the
boom in the United States rather than restrained it, because they
caused massive inflows of liquidity into the US financial system,
lowered import-price inflation, increased apparent productivity and
prompted further spending by US consumers enriched by the wealth effect
of rising equity and real-estate markets despite a slowing of wage
increases.
This was
precisely what Fed chairman Greenspan did in the 1990s in the name of
preemptive measures against inflation. Dollar hegemony enabled the
United States to print dollars to fight domestic inflation, causing a
huge debt bubble with price deflation, pushing up equity prices, which
is called growth, not inflation.
The
transition to offshore production is the source of the productivity
boom in the United States. While published government figures of the
productivity index show a rise of nearly 70 percent since 1974, the
actual rise is between zero and 10 percent in many sectors if the
effect of imports is removed from the calculation. The lower values are
consistent with the real-life experience of members of the blue-collar
working class and the white-collar middle class who have to work longer
hours to service their debts. Neither the recovery nor the recent
correction of the exchange rate of the dollar will restore
manufacturing jobs in the US, unless the US is prepared to see its GDP
drop by 25 percent. This is why Gregory Mankiw, chairman of the White
House Council of Economic Advisers, said last week that outsourcing is
a plus for the economy in the long run.
|
|
|
|
|