|
Greenspan - the Wizard of Bubbleland
By
Henry
C.K. Liu
Part I: Greenspan
- Bubble Wizard
Part II: The Repo Time Bomb
Part
III: How the US Money Market
Really Works
This
article appeared in AToL
on October 27, 2005
In order to understand the systemic risk implications of the
astronomical growth of the repo market, it is necessary to have some
basic knowledge
of the dollar money market, of which the repo market has become a major
component. The telling information is
that repos now chalk up an average daily trading volume of about $5
trillion in
the US, accounting for half of the money supply ($9.97 trillion as of
September
2005).
Conventional perception notwithstanding, the repo market is no
longer as
risk-free as presumed because the money-creating proceeds from repos
are mostly
channeled towards speculation that contributes to systemic risks.
The risk of contagion, a term given to the
process of distressed contracts dragging down healthy contracts in the
same
market as speculators throw good money after bad to try to stem the
sudden tide
of temporary losses, can be magnified by the widespread use of repos.
The money deposited by commercial banks at the central bank
is the real money in the banking system; other versions of what is
commonly
thought of as money are merely promises to pay real money. These
promises to
pay are circulatory multiples of real money. For general purposes,
people
perceive money as the amount shown in financial transactions or amount
shown in
their bank accounts. But bank accounts record both credit and debits
that
cancel each other. Only the remaining central-bank
money after aggregate settlement is real. Real money, more
properly
called final money, can take
only one of two forms: 1) physical cash, which is rarely used in
wholesale
financial markets, and 2) central-bank money. The currency component of
the
money supply is far smaller than the deposit component.
Currency and bank reserves together make up the monetary
base, sometimes known as high-powered money. The Federal Reserve (Fed)
has the
power to control the issuance of both of these components of the
monetary base.
By adjusting the levels of banks’ reserve balances, the Fed can achieve
a
desired rate of growth of deposits and of the money supply over time.
When
market participants and banks change the ratio of their currency and
reserves
to deposits, the Fed can offset the effect on the money supply by
changing
reserves and/or currency. The Fed and the US Treasury supply banks with
the
currency their customers demand, and when their demand falls, accept a
return
flow from the banks. The Fed debits banks’ reserves when it provides
currency,
and credits their reserves when they return currency. In a fractional
reserve
banking system, drains of currency from banks reduce their reserves,
and unless
the Fed provides adequate additional amounts of currency and reserves,
a
multiple contraction of deposits results, reducing the quantity of
money in the
economy.
Banks can create loan money out of central bank high power
money from a partial reserve regime. For
example, $1,000 of high power money with a bank reserve requirement of
10% can
create $7,922 of new loans, each time holding back 10% reserve from the
resultant deposit from the borrower before loaning it out again. As the
bank
reserve requirement falls, the amount of bank-created loan money rises.
Money
deposited by customers with a commercial bank is not final money, as it
is
merely a promise to pay by one party to another. When a bank customer
writes a
bank check to pay another party, the money in his account shifts to the
payee’s
account within the banking system, even if the shift is between banks. No money is added or removed from the money
supply. Money is merely shifted from one account to another within the
same
bank or from one bank to another within the banking system.
The US central bank, the Federal Reserve System, is composed
of twelve regional reserve banks and money at any of these regional
reserve
banks is final money. Most banks use an account at the Federal Reserve
Bank of
New York to settle US dollar activities in the wholesale financial
markets. The
European Central Bank (ECB) is part of the European System of national
Central
Banks, which includes the Bundesbank (Germany’s national central bank),
the
Banque de France, the Banca d’Italia, and others in the euro zone.
Money
denominated in euros at any one of the eurozone’s National Central
Banks (NCBs)
is final money. In sum, the monetary definition of money is money on
account at
the central bank. Any other form of money is really just a promise to
pay
central-bank money before final clearing.
The main purpose of an interbank deposit market, a money
market, is to equalize the payment system among banks. Banks attract
deposits
by offering interest payments. They make a profit out of deposits from
customers by lending the deposited money at a higher rate to other
customers or
to other banks. Banks lend money to each other in all major currencies
of
market relevance in globalized financial markets at agreed interest
rates and
agreed maturities. Typical maturities for interbank money range from
one day
for overnight money to 6
months, and even out to 1 year, though with much less active trading in
the
longer maturities. Funds at each bank are swept electronically at the
end of
each business day for interbank lending.
The money market is so important that many banks maintain
active screens showing the latest prices at which they are willing to
borrow
and lend. At anytime on a trading day, a major money center bank would
post a
particular rate at which it is willing to accept 3-month deposits, say
3.4%,
and to lend to other high-quality banks for the same period at a higher
rate,
say 3.45%. The bank is making a market
in these deposits, bidding for
3-month funds at one rate and offering
3-month funds at a higher rate. The intent of such market-making is to
profit
from the bid-offer spread. Banks
lend to customer at prime rate plus,
usually a few percentage points higher than they can borrow at
interbank
rates. A bank with excess funds that
cannot be lent at prime rates will lend to other banks with needs to
lend more
than funds at their disposal.
An institutional/corporate borrower which wants to borrow
funds for 6 months has several options. One would be to borrow funds
for 6
months from the commercial bank at the screen price of say 3.53%. But there are alternatives. It can borrow the
money for only 3 months (at the rate of 3.45%), and after 3 months
re-borrow
the money, or roll over the loan at then higher or lower prevailing
rate. Why
do this? To have the same cost as a 6-month loan, the re-borrowing
would have
to be at 3.58%, as the 6-month rate is the average of 3.45% and 3.58%,
the
rates for the first and second 3-month periods respectively. If the
borrower
thinks that in 3 months’ time, the cost of 3-month money will be less
than
3.58%, then it would be cheaper overall for it to borrow now for 3
months at
3.45%, and then in 3 months to re-borrow at the rate then prevailing.
If it
thinks that in 3 months’ time the cost of borrowing for 3 months is
likely to
be higher than 3.58%, it should borrow for the entire 6-month period
now.
So the breakeven
of money. The current price, also known as the cost of 3-month
money in 3 months’
time is 3.58%. This is the forward
pricespot price, of 3-month money is
3.45%; the 3-month forward price of 3-month money is 0.13% over spot.
Market
prices are implying that short-term interest rates are rising. The
borrowing
institution or corporation has still more choices. If it believes that
rates
are unlikely to rise, then it might be cheapest to borrow for 1 day,
and
re-borrow the money each subsequent day. Or if it thinks that rates are
about
to rise to very high levels, the best course would be to borrow money
for 1
year (at 3.65%), and in 6 months to lend at the then-prevailing rate,
hopefully
much higher then. No
matter
which view it takes, by choosing to borrow money
at one maturity rather than another, the borrower is implicitly
expressing an
opinion on the future path of short-term rates.
That opinion is
measured, and
can only be measured, against the current forward prices. A long-term
borrower
cannot avoid some form of implicit speculation; by choosing to borrow
at one
maturity rather than another, it is taking a view on the future path of
interest rates, and that view should be measured against the market’s
forward
prices. Thus risk is inherent in any financial commitment over time,
even if
both the rate and duration are fixed, in which case the risk is in
opportunity
cost. The risk for each market participant is related to the opinions
of other
market participants. Contrarians to market sentiment risk profit and
loss. This is the basic logic of technical
analysis
which is concerned with market behavior resulting from market sentiment
as
opposed to fundamental analysis which is concerned with economic
fundamentals
of supply and demand.
As Keynes famously
said, markets can stay irrational longer than market participants can
stay
liquid. The only exception is the
central bank operating in a fiat currency regime. Only the Fed has the
power to
defy market sentiments which explains why market participants try
desperately
to second guess pending Fed decisions on interest rates by informing on
the
ideology and decision-making rationale of the Fed.
The same applies to exchange rates of currencies. By
selecting which currency to borrow or lend and the rates and maturities
at
which loans are structured, borrowers and lenders express their views
on the
future path of exchange rates of particular currencies. The aggregate
effect of
market participant opinions determines the market price of money and
the
exchange value of all freely convertible and floating currencies. This
is how
currencies are at times attacked by speculators who manage to create
market
sentiments against particular currencies regardless of fundamentals.
Central
banks intervene from time to time to defy market sentiments by making
market
speculation unprofitable. In recent decades , the spectacular growth of
the
size of the foreign exchange market has made central bank intervention
less
effective. Though not the biggest market participants, central banks
have
unlimited fund denominated in their national currencies to effectuate
short-term rates within a policy framework. For
dollars, the Fed calls all the shots, as
it alone can print dollars
at will. And since the dollar is the
world’s major reserve currency for international trade and since all
key
commodities are denominated in dollars, the Fed commands a
disproportional
influence on the global money markets.
Insolvency risk, also known as credit or default risk, is
faced by all market participants except the Fed which alone can print
dollars
at will. Foreign central banks can print national currencies but they
cannot
print dollars. Thus all foreign central banks face insolvent risks on
dollar
obligations. When that happens, foreign central banks have to turn to
the
International Monetary Fund (IMF) as a lender of last resort to avoid
default
on their dollar obligations. Banks deal not only with one another and
not only
with top-quality financial institutions from countries with clear and
competent
financial supervision, but also with riskier entities (individuals,
trusts,
partnerships, companies, or even governments). With some of these
entities, the
risk of insolvency is significant and sometimes unpredictable.
A
solution to
credit risk can be found in the repo
market. The bank lends money to a borrower collateralized by government
bonds
of the same market value. Under normal circumstances, after the loan
matures,
the borrower returns the money plus interest, and the bank returns the
collaterals. But if the borrower should become insolvent or is forced
to
default on the loan for any reason, the lender can recover its loss by
selling
the collateral that it holds.
Interest rate volatility affects the market value of securities,
even government securities. Thus the
Fed’s interest rate policy affects the risk level of the repo market.
Thus the
money market is a game in which market participants guess the future
decisions
of the Fed, and their implication on market forces. Both the supply of
money
and the demand for money as affected by its price (interest rates) are
set by
the Fed based on macroeconomic theories that are ideological derived,
not
scientifically validated. On this arbitrary monetary foundation set by
a handful
appointed individuals is built free market capitalism in a democracy.
On one
level, the institution of central banking is politically independent;
on a more
fundamental level, central banking defies the most basic principles of
democracy and free markets.
For the lender, the advantage of collateralization is that
it almost eliminates credit risk. For the borrower, the disadvantage is
that
collateral must first be found. The borrower’s disadvantage and the
lender's
advantage are reflected in the price of the loan. The interest rate on
a
collateralized loan is below that on a non-collateralized loan. Within
the same
currency, the spread varies across maturities and according to the
quality of
the collateral and the counterparty, but a typical unsecured-secured
differential is 0.1% to 0.5% for borrowers of equal credit rating.
Commercial bank accounts with the central bank are subject
to different rules about overdrafts in different countries. Some
central banks
prohibit overdrafts; at the end of each day no account may be
overdrawn. Other
central banks are less strict, specifying that every account must have
a
positive balance on average, where the averaging is conducted over a
period of
time known as a reserve period.
Whichever the case, commercial banks need to avoid having an overdraft
at the
central bank, either on average or every day by borrowing money from
another
bank. Bank-to-bank borrowing can only relocate rather than extinguish
the
aggregate overdraft in the banking system.
The escape to systemic
aggregate
overdraft is to borrow money directly from the central bank or from the
repo
market when the Fed injects money into it through the monetizing of
sovereign
debt by lending against government securities held by non-bank
entities.
Government securities sold to private buyers caused money to be
withdrawn from
the economy. This money reenters the economy when the government spends
it.
When the holders use such securities as collaterals to secure new loans
in the
repo market, new money is in fact created.
The Discount Rate
The greatest power bestowed on the Federal Reserve is the
setting of the discount rate - the rate of interest charged by the
Reserve
Banks when lending to member institutions collateralized by government
securities. Raising the discount rate generally increases the cost of
borrowing
and tightens the money supply and slows the economy, while dropping it
expands
the money supply and stimulates economic activity, since banks set
their loan
rates above the discount rate, and not by market forces.
Fed discount rates and Fed funds rate targets
are inputs into market conditions, not outputs from market forces.
The term "discount rate," although widely used, is
actually an anachronism. Since 1971, Reserve Bank loans to depository
institutions have been secured by advances. Interest is computed on an
accrual
basis and paid to the Fed at the time of loan repayment.
The interest rate charged by a Federal
Reserve Bank on short-term loans to depository institutions is referred
to as
the discount rate. The discount rate is important for two reasons: (1)
it
affects the cost of reserves borrowed from the Fed and (2) changes in
the rate
can be interpreted as an indicator of monetary policy.
Increases in the discount rate generally
reflect the Fed’s concern over inflationary pressures, while decreases
reflect
a concern over economic weakness or deflation. Discount-window lending,
open
market operations to effect changes in reserves to set Fed funds rates,
and bank
reserve requirements are the three main monetary policy tools of the
Federal
Reserve System. Together, they dictate the short-term cost and
availability of
money and credit.
Usually, the discount rate is less than the federal-funds
and other money-market interest rates. However, the Fed does not allow
banks to
borrow at the discount window for profit. Thus, it monitors
discount-window and
federal funds activity to make sure that banks are not borrowing from
the Fed
in order to lend at a higher rate in the federal funds market.
During
periods of
monetary ease, such as now, the spread between the federal funds and
discount
rates may narrow or even disappear briefly because depository
institutions have
less of a need to borrow reserves in the money market. Under these
conditions,
the Fed may adjust the discount rate in order to reestablish the
customary
spread. Discount window loans are
granted only after Reserve Banks are convinced that borrowers have
fully used
reasonably available alternative sources of funds, such as the federal
funds
market and loans from correspondents and other institutional sources.
The
latter sources include the credit programs that the Federal Home Loan
Banks and
the Central Liquidity Facility of the National Credit Union
Administration
provide for their members.
Usually, relatively few depository
institutions
borrow at the discount window in any one week. Consequently, such
lending
provides only a small fraction of the banking system’s total reserves.
All
depository institutions that maintain reservable transaction accounts
or
non-personal time deposits are entitled to borrow at the discount
window. This
includes commercial banks, thrift institutions, and US branches and
agencies of
foreign banks. Prior to the passage of the Depository Institutions
Deregulation
and Monetary Control Act of 1980, discount window borrowing generally
had been
restricted to commercial banks that were members of the Federal Reserve
System.
Changes in the discount rate generally have been infrequent.
From 1980 through 1990, for example, there were 29 rate changes, and
the
duration of the periods between adjustments ranged from two weeks to 22
months.
However, following those 22 months without a change, the Fed cut the
discount
rate seven times in the period of economic sluggishness from December
1990 to
July 1992 -- from 7% at the start of the period to 3% at the end. From
May 1994
to February 1995, when the Fed was concerned about the threat of
inflation, it
raised the discount rate four times -- from 3% to 5.25%. Changes in the
discount rate often lag changes in market rates.
Thus, even though the
Fed
pushed the federal funds rate down 25 basis points in July 1995, as of
December
it had not cut the discount rate. Since 1980, the changes in the
discount rate
have been by either one half or a full percentage point, although
quarter-point
changes were made in earlier years. The lowest discount rate charged by
the New
York Fed was 0.5%, which was in effect from 1942 through 1946; the
highest rate
was 14%, which lasted from May to November 1981. In 1999, the discount
rate was
4.5% while Fed funds rate was 4.75% and 3-month T-bills rate was 4.27%.
On
September 13, 2005, the discount rate was 4.5% (effective since August
9, 2005)
while Fed funds rate target was 3.5% (effective since August 9, 2005),
the overnight
repo rate was 3.45%, 3-month T-bill was 3.45%, GE 30-44-day commercial
paper
was 3.68% and 3-month LIBOR (London interbank offered rate) was 3.87%. Effective September 20, 2005, the discount
rate was raised to 4.75%; the Fed funds rate target was raised to 3.75%. On October 19, 2005, the overnight repo rate
was
3.70%, 3-month T-bill was 3.785%, GE 30-44-day commercial paper was
3.90% and
3-month LIBOR (London interbank offered rate) was 4.35%.
Today, while the spread between the discount
rate and the Fed funds rate is zero. The repos market continues to
expand,
giving evidence that the borrowing is not being done by depository
institutions. In other words, the credit
market has largely run away from banks.
Fed Funds
Federal funds include funds deposited by commercial banks at
the Federal Reserve Banks, including funds in excess of bank reserve
requirements. But Fed funds can be created at will by the Fed now that
the
dollar is a fiat currency since 1971, not backed by gold. Commercial
banks may lend
federal funds to one another on an overnight basis at the Fed funds
rate, which
is the most sensitive indicator of the direction of interest rates
since it is
set daily by the market in response to the Fed’s Open-Market operation:
the
buying or selling of government securities in the repo market to meet
Fed funds
rate targets. Thus the real function of sovereign debt is to provide an
instrument through the buying and selling of which the Fed can inject
money
into or withdraw money from the money supply without appearing to
create or
destroy money while actually doing so.
Notwithstanding conventional perception,
sovereign debt is not incurred
by fiscal deficits which are created by government reluctance to raise
taxes to
cover expenditure. Fiscal deficits are the government’s way to inject
money
into the economy independent of the central bank, to avoid raising
taxes which
is government’s way of withdrawing money from the economy.
A government fiscal surplus shrinks the
economy in two ways: it drains money from the money supply and it
prevents
money from reentering the economy through government spending. Thus
fiscal
deficits are not inherently bad for the economy, especially for an
economy that
is underperforming. It all depends on how the deficit spending is used.
If it
is used for increasing employment and improving infrastructure or
education or
health care, thus expanding the slowing economy, it is good; if it is
used to
make war or speculation, thus contributing to debt bubbles, it is bad.
The US money market is basically for short-term debt
instruments generally collateralized by treasury bills as default-free
securities. Short-term interest rates are basically determined by the
Fed’s
action in the money markets, in which instruments such as treasury
bills,
commercial deposits, euro-deposits, commercial paper, and repurchase
agreements
are traded. It is in the money markets, that the Federal Reserve
conducts most
of its transaction activity and attempts to meet its short-term
interest rate
target.
Two key interest rates dominate the activity of the US money markets:
1.
The
Federal funds rate
2.
The repo rate
These two rates, though closely connected, serve opposite
functions. In normal usage, both of the
above rates are overnight rates based upon a 360-day year. The Federal
funds
rate is the interest rate that banks charge each other when they lend
reserves
to one another. Money supply calculations are dominated by
consideration of
bank demand and time deposits, which lie on the liability side of a
commercial
bank’s balance sheet. Reserves make up a
part of the bank's assets. Banks that are members of the Federal
Reserve System
are required to hold cash reserves against their deposit liabilities.
The rules
for the reserve requirements, once very simple, are now quite entangled.
Even if reserves were not a legal requirement, it is clear prudence
would ensure that banks would hold a certain percentage of their assets
in the
form of cash reserves. It is common to think of commercial banks as
passive
receivers of deposits from their customers and, for many purposes, this
is
still an accurate view. This passive view of bank activity is
misleading when
it comes to considering what determines the nation's money supply and
credit. Loan activity by banks plays a
fundamental
role in determining the money supply. As
economists know, when a loan is made between parties, money is created. The effects of bank-created money are well
understood by economists but the effects of non-bank-created money are
not.
The banking system as an institution is the venue through
which the Fed, as a central bank, manages the money supply in the
nation’s
economy. The instrument to effectuate
this management is the Fed funds rate, which set the price of funds
when banks
borrow from each other. The repo market
is a venue through which banks and other market participants can bypass
the
Fed’s money supply policy targets. Thus Fed funds are institutional
opposites
of repo proceeds, each serving opposite functions. Fed funds are used
by the
Fed to control the money supply created by bank lending while the repo
market
is where banks and other market participants can seek to free
themmselves from
the Fed’s control. In practice, it is commonly assumed that the Fed
sets the Federal
funds rate while in reality, the Fed sets a Fed funds rate target and
tries to
move the Fed funds rate toward the target by influencing the repo rate
with
open market operations.
Money Supply
Concepts of the money supply are meant to identify the quantity
of the one commodity (money) that is
decreed
as legal tender for settling financial obligations within the economy
as a
whole. Like other economic concepts, there is no perfect conceptual
definition
of money supply. Most economists have come to accept some vague
intuitive
understanding of the notion of money supply. Measuring
the money supply, in practice, is
mostly opinion-based, and a
variety of money supply measures are currently in use. The most
frequently
cited measures of the money supply are: M1 and M2.
M1 includes demand deposits (including now
accounts) and coin and currency held by the non-bank public. M2 is M1
plus
commercial deposits. M2 is the most widely followed money supply
measure. M3 is equal to M2 plus time
deposits over
$100,000 and term repo agreements. A fourth category, known a L,
measures M3
plus all other liquid assets such as Treasury bills, savings bonds,
commercial
paper, bankers’ acceptances and Eurodollar holdings of US residents
(non-bank).
Banks hold cash reserves in proportion to their deposit
liabilities. If a bank’s cash reserves increase, then the bank may be
able to
increase its demand deposit liabilities correspondingly. The total cash
reserves of the commercial banking system serve to constrain the total
deposit
liabilities of the system. The daily ebb and flow of commercial and
private
transactions is constantly shifting cash reserves from bank to bank.
Total cash
reserves are also mildly affected as coins and notes held by the public
are
altered through daily transactions. Broadly speaking, the daily
transaction
activity does not affect the total cash reserves held by the commercial
banking
system, merely the distribution of those reserves among the various
individual
commercial banks.
If cash reserves of a commercial bank begin to decline, it
will eventually be deemed, legally or prudentially, inadequate for the
outstanding demand deposit and time deposit liabilities. The bank must
then
either rebuild its cash reserve levels or cut back on its deposit
liabilities.
If it cannot stem the decline in cash reserves, then the bank
ultimately must
reduce deposit liabilities. Since these deposit liabilities are the
most
important component of the money supply, the money supply ultimately
must
decline if cash reserves of the banking system fall sufficiently. A
sufficient
decline in commercial bank cash reserves will ultimately cause a drop
in the
money supply. Conversely, expansion of the money supply is ultimately
limited
by the aggregate cash reserves of the commercial banking system. At least that is how it works theoretically
before the spectacular growth of structured finance (derivatives) the
impact of
which on the virtual money supply is not well understood even by
experts.
The Fed is frequently mentioned as having a major influence
on the economy mostly because the Fed has the ability to change the
cash
reserves of the commercial banking system easily and essentially
immediately,
through its Open Market Operation in the repo market. Normally, open
market
operations are transactions that involve the central bank in buying or
selling
(with money) government securities. The Fed affects open market
purchases by
buying treasury bills or notes or bonds on the open market and paying
central
bank money. It really doesn't make any difference what the Fed buys so
long as
the Fed pays money that will be deposited in the private banking
system.
The
point is that the money goes from the Fed which has an unlimited
amount, to the
private banking system which has a limited amount. Whether the money is
given
freely, dropped from helicopters or in exchange for treasury securities
is
irrelevant because fiat money itself has no intrinsic value, the value
lies in
what fiat money can buy. And that value is determined by the aggregate
money
supply in relation to the aggregate amount of assets. Prices go up or
down only
when the relationship between the money supply and the amount of assets
changes. When more money is issued along with a growth of assets, there
will be
no asset price changes, or no inflation even if the economy expands. When asset prices rise, it reflects a change
in the money supply/asset relationship, meaning more money chasing the
same
number of assets. Thus when asset prices rise, it is not necessarily a
healthy
sign for the economy. It reflects a troublesome condition in which
additional
money is not creating correspondingly more assets.
It is a fundamental self-deception for
economists to view asset price appreciation as economic growth. A
housing
bubble is an example of this troublesome condition.
When prices fall, economists call it deflation. Deflation
is not always caused by the economy
not having enough money. It can be caused by an excessive liquidity
preference
on the part of market participants. When that happens, a liquidity trap
develops in which market participants withhold money waiting for still
lower
prices. The Japanese economy in the
1990s was the clearest example of a liquidity trap, in which even
negative interest
rates failed to cure deflation.
Financial markets are obsessed with Fed activities. It is
common to hear or read that the Fed has eased or tightened. Wall Street
thinks
of a lowering of the federal funds rate as Fed easing. Little or no
attention
is paid to money supply aggregates or Fed balance sheet aggregates by
Wall Street
commentators. The error of Wall Street’s view is that the Fed does not
directly
participate in any way in the Federal funds market which is strictly an
inter-bank market for cash reserves. The Federal funds rate is
determined,
during the course of a market day, by supply and demand by commercial
banks --
the Fed funds rate is a restricted market-determined rate. It is not
set by the
Fed or by anyone. The Fed merely sets a Fed funds rate target. The
reason that Wall
Street monitors the Federal funds rate target as an indication of Fed
policy is
that the Federal funds rate closely tracks the repo rate that the Fed
actively
influences during most market days. Every business day morning at 11:45
a.m.
Eastern Time, the NY Fed announces what it intends to do in the repo
market.
Changes in the repo rate are normally quickly followed by changes in
the Fed funds
rate. Thus, indirectly, the Fed appears to be able to influence the
Federal
funds rate through its impact upon the repo rate.
Monetarists consider the money supply, especially the growth
rate of the money supply, to be the main instrument of Fed policy.
Thus, if
money supply growth is increasing, then the Fed is said to be easing.
If money
supply growth is decreasing, then the Fed is tightening. This concept
of easing
and tightening has the virtue that the Fed is known to control, with
varying
degrees of precision, the growth rate of the money supply. In other
words,
whatever the path of the money supply, there is no question that the
Fed has
the instruments at its disposal to control (with some error) the growth
rate of
the money supply. But the rapid growth of structured finance has
created
questions on the validity of this view. Money
now, especially virtual money is created
quite independent of Fed
action and money creation has become much less sensitive to interest
rate
fluctuations. This explains why the measured pace at which the Fed has
been
raising the Fed funds rate target has little direct or immediate effect
on the
housing bubble.
Non-monetarists subscribe to the view that Fed easing means
the Fed lowers interest rates. They are often not very specific about
how these
rates are lowered or how the Fed should go about doing this. There are
often
periods (as between 1990-1991) where interest rates drop but money
growth is
also falling. Non-monetarists (and Wall Streeters) view periods like
these as
Fed easing episodes, while Monetarists argue that these are
(implicitly)
periods of Fed tightening.
There is no generally accepted empirical test of Fed easing
or tightening when money growth and interest rates are moving in the
same
direction, as it appears to be happening now. The Federal Reserve is
active on
almost any given day in the repo market. Commercial banks can sell
assets to
raise cash (possibly liquidating loans); or they can borrow the cash.
The repo
market provides a way to do the latter while making it appear that they
are
doing the former.
Repos Increase
Systemic Risk
It is a good question why is a loan called a repo. The
answer is that the notion of a repurchase agreement was a fiction
dreamed up to
minimize the impact of such transactions on bank and broker-dealer
capital
requirements. If these transactions had been called loans, then banks
(and broker-dealers)
would be required to set aside cash (or perhaps other capital if a
broker-dealer) against such loans. By inventing the fiction of calling
what is
actually a loan by some other name, banks and broker-dealers were able
to bypass
banking regulation and reserve less cash/capital against such
activities.
Convertible bonds are another type of loan that can be incurred by
corporation
off the books. Repos obviously increase
systemic risk in the banking system as well as in the monetary system,
particularly when the daily repos volume has grown to $5 trillion and
rising by
the week.
To raise cash, a commercial bank normally sells so-called
secondary reserves consisting of treasury bills and other short term
debt
assets, before resorting to other more drastic measures like the
liquidation of
loans, selling fixed assets of the bank and so forth. Or a bank can
borrow by
borrowing reserves directly from other commercial banks in the federal
funds
market. The rate for such borrowings would be the prevailing Federal
funds rate
that follows the law of supply and demand set by Fed open market
operations. Or
a bank can do reverse repos. Mechanically, it would send out secondary
reserves
to some third party in exchange for a cash loan. When the loan
terminates, the bank
will receive back its secondary reserves that had been pledged for the
repo. Such transactions will occur at
the prevailing repo rate. A default will
saddle the creditor with a loss equal to the spread between the old and
new
prevailing repo rate. Or a bank can issue commercial deposits to the
public
(which will simultaneously increase reserves and deposits). Such
issuance
(sales, really) will be transacted at the prevailing cd rates corrected
for the
credit quality of the issuing bank. Or a bank can borrow from the Fed
at the
Federal Reserve Discount Window. This type of borrowing takes place at
the Fed
discount rate, an announced rate that the Fed changes from time to time.
Because banks are looking at these two alternatives as ways
of raising cash, there will be a tendency for rates to move together.
If the
Fed funds rate is high, but the repo rate is low, then banks will be
more
likely to raise cash by doing reverse repos than by borrowing funds.
This will
tend to
move those rates together, similarly with cd rates.
Thus if the Fed is able to raise or lower the repo rate, this should
have an
impact on the Fed funds rate in the same direction (It also should
impact the
cd rates through similar reasoning). The Fed is likely to be able to
control the
Federal funds rate if it can control the repo rate. Most observers seem
to feel
that the Fed can routinely control the daily Federal funds rate because
the
Fed, in their eyes, can control the repo rate.
Until recently, it was not obvious that doing repos and
reverses had any real impact, other than very temporarily, upon either
the cash
reserves of the banking system or the repo rate. These conditions have
fundamentally changed. The Bond Market
Association reports that the average daily
volume of
total outstanding repurchase (repo) and reverse repo agreement
contracts
totaled $5.47 trillion in the first half of 2005, an increase of 17.4%
from the
$4.66 trillion from the daily average outstanding during the same
period a year
ago. The repo market has become
the biggest run-away credit window outside of the control of the Fed.
Yet, the
prevailing consensus view remains that Fed activity in the repo market
should
be essentially the mechanism for targeting the Federal funds rate in
the manner
outlined above.
John Kambhu, vice president of the NY Federal Reserve Bank,
observes that convergence trading, in which speculators trade on the
expectation that asset prices will converge to their fundamental, or
normal,
levels, typically stabilizes markets. By countering and smoothing price
shocks,
these trades can enhance market liquidity. However, if convergence
traders
close out their positions prematurely, asset prices will tend to
diverge
further from their fundamental levels. Both stabilizing and
destabilizing forces
in the market are attributable to convergence trading. The swap spread
tends to
converge to its fundamental level more slowly when the capital of
traders has
been weakened by trading losses, while higher trading risk can
sometimes cause
the spread to diverge from its fundamental level. Although convergence
trading
typically absorbs shocks, an unusually large disruption can be
amplified when
traders close out their positions prematurely. Destabilizing shocks in
the swap
spread are associated with a fall in repo volume consistent with the
premature
closing out of convergence trading positions. Repo volume also falls in
response to convergence trading losses. Kambhu explains that taken
together,
these results are consistent with the argument that while convergence
trading
tends to be a stabilizing force, the risks in trading, as reflected in
repo
volume, on occasion can lead to behavior that destabilizes the swap
spread. That
occasion will occur as unpredictably but surely as a devastating
hurricane
hitting New Orleans.
And the rate at which the central bank lends money can
indeed be chosen at will by the central bank; this is the rate that
makes the
financial headlines. In the US, central bank lending rate is known as
the Fed
funds rate. The Fed sets a target for the Fed funds rate which its Open
Market
Committee tries to match by lending or borrowing in the money market.
Thus
fundamentally, the money market is not a free market, but one dictated
by the
central bank with a particular preference for the resultant state of
the
economy. The so-called free-market capitalism operates through this
command
money market. Thus at the heart of the
free-market ideology is a fiat money system set by command of the
central bank. The Fed is the head of the
central bank snake
because the dollar is the key reserve currency for international trade. The global money market is a dollar market.
All other currencies markets revolve around the dollar market.
When a government’s treasury issues sovereign debt, the
money proceeds go to finance the portion of the fiscal budget not
covered by
taxes. When government runs a fiscal deficit, it takes money from the
private
sector by issuing sovereign debt and spends the money back in the
private
sector. Thus the important issue is not if the government runs a fiscal
deficit, but how the fiscal deficit is spent. A fiscal deficit does not
reduce
the total money supply; it only increases the amount of debt.
But
monetary
economist such as Hyman Minsky asserts that whenever credit is issued,
money is
created. Thus the issuing of government bonds is the government’s way
of
issuing money without the involvement of the central bank. This is why
Greenspan is always warning about the fiscal deficit. Yet the notion
that
government borrowing crowds out private borrowing is controversial.
Fiscal
deficits do not even directly affect short-term interest rates which
are set by
the central bank. If the government
wishes, it can take money directly from the central bank which is
legislatively
authorized to issue money by fiat as the sole legal tender in the
country. A
country’s fiat money enjoys currency because the government accepts it
for
payment of taxes. Fiat money is in fact a form of tax credit, or
sovereign
credit. Sovereign debt instruments do
have a market function: they provide the assets that a central bank can
buy or
sell in the repo market to meet its Fed funds rate target.
Next: The Global Money and Currency Markets
|
|
|
|
|