Wages of Neoliberalism
Part III: China’s
Internal Debt Problem
By
Henry C.K. Liu
Part I: Core
Contradcitions
Part II: The US-China Trade Imbalance
This article appeared in AToL on May 27, 2006
In 2005 the Standing Committee of China’s National People’s
Congress (NPC), the legislative body, ratified a resolution on the
implementation of a new national debt management system. From 2006 on, the NPC will
examine for approval the aggregate national debt balance, rather than just the annual amount
of new national debt to be issued. Statistics released by the Budgetary Work
Committee of the NPC Standing Committee showed that by the end of 2004, China’s
national debt balance reached 2.96 trillion yuan ($370 billion), including 2.88
trillion yuan ($360 billion) of domestic debt and 82.8 billion yuan ($10
billion) of foreign debt. China’s 2004 national debt burden rate was 21.6% of GDP,
far lower than the EU-designated warning level of 60% for its members, a generally accepted international standard.
The Chinese Ministry of Finance reported that aggregate national debt balance
rose to 3.26 trillion yuan ($407.5 billion) in 2005, but it fell to only 18% of
2005 GDP of 18.23 trillion yuan ($2.28 trillion). This reflects the effect on
economic policy analysis with dynamic scoring in which the growth impact of the
national debt on the economy can outstrip its nominal rise. By comparison, the
US national debt stood at $8.4 trillion as of April 13, 2006, or 65% of
forecasted GDP. About $4.9 trillion of the US national debt is held by the public
and $3.5 trillion is held intra-governmentally. US national debt is about 20
times more than China’s on a nominal basis, 5 times on a purchasing power
parity basis, almost 4 times on a debt/GDP basis and 100 times on a per capita
basis. US per capita income is about 35
times that of China in 2005, which means each US citizen is carrying almost
three times the national debt/income ratio than his/her Chinese counterpart. On
average, US wages are about 50 times those of China due to higher income
disparity in China.
The National Debt
The
national debt is a financing bridge over the gap between a nation’s fiscal
policy and its monetary policy. Fiscal policy determines government revenue and
expenditures while monetary policy determines money supply and short-term
interest rates. A prudent fiscal policy can moderate the need for national debt
by either cutting expenditures or raising taxes or both. Monetary policy ease
can also reduce the need for national debt by the issuance of more fiat money
which is an instrument of sovereign credit backed by government’s authority to
collect taxes payable in fiat currency. A rise in the money supply lowers
interest rates in the short term but the resultant rise in inflation may cause
interest rate to rise in the long term. A tax increase takes money from the
private sector into the public sector and unless the government spends all the
tax increases back into the economy, it essentially reduces the amount of
sovereign credit in the economy. Unless there are excessive inflationary trends
going forward, a government who desires an expansionary economy has no business
running a fiscal surplus, particularly if the economy is plagued with
overcapacity. The controversy is how the surplus revenue should be spent to
yield the most beneficial and equitable effects for the economy. The
national debt serves other important financial purposes for the economy. A
government securities market allows the central bank to carry out open market
operations to meet short-term interest rate targets and to provide a credit
rating anchor for the nation’s debt market.
Dollar Hegemony Eliminates Default Risk for US Government Securities
Because of dollar hegemony, a peculiar phenomenon of the dollar, a fiat
currency, assuming the role of a key reserve currency for international trade
and finance, US government securities do not carry default risks, as the US can
print dollars at will with little short-term penalty. The only risk US government securities carry
is inflation, a prospect that the Federal Reserve, its central bank, can
control through interest rate policy.
High Fed Funds rates can reduce dollar inflation under normal
circumstances, unless the economy is plagued by a debt bubble, in which case
high Fed Funds rates can actually add to inflation.
Government
securities of other nations denominated in dollars carry default risks as these
governments cannot print dollars. Even
government securities denominated in local currencies that are freely
convertible carry default risks because the foreign exchange market limits the
ability of these governments to print their own local currencies relative to
the size of their foreign exchange holdings.
In that sense, dollar hegemony has reduced all freely convertible and
free-floating currencies to the status of derivatives of the dollar. The governments of such currencies have
forfeited their monetary sovereignty with which to manage their economies. The
currencies of these nations no longer derive their value only from the strength
of their economies, but also from the value of the dollar, rising or falling
against the dollar as a bench mark. The Federal Reserves of the US has become a
super-national monetary authority through dollar hegemony, framing policies
that prioritize the needs of the US from which the prosperity of the rest of
the world must derive. This is why after
the abandonment of the Bretton Woods fixed exchange rates regime based on a
gold-backed dollar, the US has been pushing a global floating exchange rates
regime based on a fiat dollar in order to impose dollar hegemony on world
finance.
Interest Rate Stability or Money Supply Stability
Monetary
policy authorities have a choice between interest rate stability and money
supply stability, but no monetary system that operates on fiat money can have
both options. The national debt is the lowest cost a nation can borrow. Sovereign debt interest rates act as a bench
mark for other debts because sovereign credit is superior to private sector
credit under normal conditions. When the money supply is tight, interest rates
on government bonds rise. This causes
interest rates on all private debts to rise with them. High domestic interest rates usually exert
upward pressure on the exchange rates of freely convertible currencies.
Best Use for a Fiscal Surplus
During
the years of fiscal surplus in Clinton’s second term, a policy debate surfaced
on whether to pay down the national debt or to cut taxes. The economic logic tilts in favor of tax cuts
because the national debt needs a future tax to repay it. Paying down the national debt would lower the
future tax rate so it is merely a way to defer the tax cut to the future. Thus
financially speaking, a fiscal surplus can be more effectively used to finance
an immediate tax cut to stimulate an overcapacity economy rather than to pay
down the national debt to reduce the tax burden in the future. For example, the
US national debt was paying around 6% interest while personal credit card
interest hovered around 18% in the Clinton years. But the national debt actually paid less than
6% because the recipients of the interest payments must pay income tax up to
40%, reducing the real national debt cost to the US government to around 3.5%.
The degree of progressive distribution of the tax cut has more impact on the
economy. Long-term interest rates are determined by supply and demand in the
credit market as well as the market’s judgment of the credit worthiness of the
debt issuer and the future health of the economy as affect by fiscal and
monetary policies. Thus the immediate
strengthening of the economy can also have positive effects on long-term
interest rates.
China's Shift from Proactive to Prudent Fiscal Policy
In
2006, China’s fiscal policy begins a gradual shifted from “proactive”
to
“prudent”. In the past seven years, a proactive fiscal policy added 2
percentage points to economic growth rate every year. China now
urgently needs
to deal with a series of pressing economic and social problems that
have been
created by its transition from a socialist planned economy to a
“socialist”
market economy. And all solutions point to the need for a sustainable
high economic
growth rate for decades to come. If the steps of “prudent” fiscal
adjustment are
taken too abruptly, it would lead to a slowdown in growth rate with
serious adverse
impacts on national economic performance. China does not need to slow
down its
overall growth rate as much as it needs to redress the imbalances in
its
transitional economy caused by overheated sectors caused by market
failure. It
does need to reconsider fixation on the conventional measure of growth
in narrow GDP
terms and begin to aim for balance growth with renewed focus on
domestic social
development and environmental preservation as the real engines of
growth, away
from over-reliance on export and dysfunctional domestic market forces
driven by speculation. The exchange deficit between environmental
deterioration and single-minded
industrialization is a formula for negative growth. The same is true
for the
mindless privatization of public goods.
The shift of emphasis towards balanced development does not necessarily
mean a slower growth rate. In fact, it needs an acceleration of the growth rate
measured by a more meaningful standard.
The Chinese Bond Market
In China, government bonds used to be allocated by the
issuing central government to state-owned banks as captured buyers, with funds
from depositors who had few if any alternative investment options. With the Finance
Ministry scheduled to pay back the eighteenth issuance of national debts due in
2005, China has entered a five-year peak debt repayment period. Between 2005
and 2009 the Finance Ministry’s annual debt repayment will amount to around 400
billion yuan ($50 billion). While China can easily meet this repayment
schedule, its impact on the nation’s money supply will be significant unless
new national debt is issued.
In addition, as part of the shift from a national banking
regime to a central banking regime, China is reforming its four major state
banks to become commercial banks, looking to list them in overseas equity
markets as commercial enterprises to meet WTO requirements of liberalizing its
banking sector by the end of 2006. To do so, substantial funds need to be
injected into these banks to reduce their residual bad debt ratio by the issuance of corporate
bonds and government bonds. The funds these banks need to cure their systemic
non-performing loan (NPL) problems left by the era of national banking are so huge that a considerable amount of
the bonds will have to be borne by the Finance Ministry. The resolution of
systemic NPLs will have a contracting effect in the nation’s money supply, as
the extinguishment of debt removes money from the economy. Under these
circumstances, China has decided to speed up the opening of its embryonic bond
market to foreign capital.
Similar to post-WWII Germany, China has a historical phobia
about the political impact of hyperinflation, a condition that played a major
role in the fall of the previous Nationalist government in 1949. Unlike the German Third Reich which was
deprived of foreign credit and had to rely on sovereign credit to revive the
collapsed German economy after WWI, China in the last two decades has been lured by
the availability of easy foreign credit. This is a mixed blessing. Finance globalization is an illegitimate
child of dollar hegemony which forces all nations that accept foreign credit
to emphasize low-wage export to earn dollars to repay dollar denominated
loans. Under such circumstances, export keeps domestic wages low while it ships
real wealth overseas in exchange of dollars that cannot be used in the domestic
economy.
In the early 1990s, China experienced high inflation due to disproportionate
credit expansion that came with a “proactive” fiscal policy under the
premiership of Zhu Rongji who was nicknamed the “debt premier” by his critics.
The problem was not the expansion of credit, but that such credit was used
mostly for speculative purposes. Corrective policies were subsequently introduced
to deal with debt-driven inflation and imbalances. Central regulatory controls
and new regulations over the Shanghai and Shenzhen stock exchanges were imposed
to rein in run-away speculative debt expansion. But these tightening measures
were accompanied by financial market liberalization and bank reform measures
that had countering effects on the government’s effort to deflate the
speculative debt bubble. The public soon discovered that other higher-yielding
investment options, such as the stock market and real estate, were open to them
beside bank saving accounts, without any awareness that the improved returns
were paid for with cuts in social welfare benefits and employment security until
it was too late. As US workers saw their jobs shipped overseas to low-waged
locations to provide higher returns on their pension funds, Chinese workers saw
the profits from their low wages and meager benefits shipped back to the US in
the form of Chinese foreign exchange holdings in US Treasuries.
Similar to the situation
in Japan or perhaps even inspired by it, Chinese corporations began to borrow
low-interest loans from banks to speculate in the equity and real property
markets to make easy profit rather than to invest in the plant modernization or
expansion, which was left mostly to costly foreign direct investment. Experienced
overseas speculators moved in to manipulate the small and under-regulated
Chinese equity and real property markets at the expense of inexperienced and
naïve local investors.
China's Move from National Banking to Central Banking
Until the mid-1990s, China’s state-owned banks acted mainly
as funding agents of the state in a national banking regime to fund government
economic policies. Bank profitability was not the controlling factor in loan
decisions. The Central Bank Law and the Commercial Bank Law were adopted in
1995 at the same time when a series of financial sector reforms was introduced,
including exchange rate unification, formal establishment and regulation of the
inter-bank market (IBM) for short term loans, the creation of an inter-bank
foreign exchange market (IBFEM), the start of open market operation (OMO) by the
People’s Bank of China (PBoC), the new central bank, and other market reform
measures. Together, these reform measures of 1994-95 contributed to the
development of an embryonic domestic market for government bonds (GBs) in China.
Bond markets are organized into two categories: government
bonds (GB) and corporate bonds (CB), the credit worthiness of both is rated by
independent credit rating agencies according to well-established standards,
albeit not always neutral or free of political bias. GBs are sovereign debt instruments,
guaranteed by the full faith and credit of a sovereign nation, CBs are backed
by the assets of the issuing corporation. Interest rates on all bonds are
affected by their credit ratings. Aside from the banking sector, CBs are widely
used in the Chinese telecommunication sector. It can be expected hat as the Chinese
bond market develops, the CB market will become much larger than the GB market.
The PBoC, the central bank, formulates and implements
monetary policy. The PBOC maintains the banking sector’s payment, clearing and
settlement systems, and manages official foreign exchange and gold reserves. It
oversees the State Administration of Foreign Exchange (SAFE) for setting
foreign-exchange policies. The 1995 Central Bank law gives PBoC full autonomy
in applying monetary instruments,
including setting interest rate for commercial banks and trading in government
bonds. The State Council maintains oversight of PBoC policies. China Banking Regulatory Commission (CBRC)
was officially launched on April 28, 2003, to take over the supervisory role of
the PBoC. The goal of the landmark reform is to improve the efficiency of bank
supervision and to allow the PBoC to further focus on macro economic and
currency policies.
New Commercial Banks
The CBRC is responsible for “the regulation and supervision of banks, asset
management companies, trust and investment companies as well as other deposit-taking
financial institutions. Its mission is to maintain a safe and sound banking
system in China.” As part of the 1994 monetary reform measures, commercial
lending and policy lending in the state banking sector were separated. The four
specialized banks under the aegis of the People’s Bank of China: namely, the
Bank of China (BOC), Industry and Commerce Bank of China (ICBC), China
Construction Bank (CCB), and the Agriculture Bank of China (ABC), were
transformed into independent commercial banks to be operated for profit for the
benefit of shareholders rather than to support national development aims for
the benefit of the nation, while at the same time assuming full market and
credit risks as stand-alone profit-driven commercial institutions. There are
also second-tier commercial banks and trust and investment companies. However,
the government continues to be the major shareholder in these banks and trust
companies. These new commercial banks put their funds to work in the market
where return is highest but not necessarily in the best national interest in
terms of where investment is needed most.
Policy Banks
Three policy lending banks - the Long-Term Development and
Credit Bank (DCB), the Import-Export Bank (EXIMB) and the Agricultural
Development Bank (ADB) - were also set up, separate from the commercial banks.
The function of policy banks is to grant policy loans in accordance with state
industrial policy and national plans. The capital sources of these policy banks
will be mainly government budgetary funds, social insurance, postal and
investment funds from a shrinking public sector, central bank credit and a
developing GB market.
Interest Rate Liberalization
The central government has recently allowed several small
banks to raise capital through bonds or stock issues. The reform of the banking
system has been accompanied by the central bank’s aim to gradually decontrol
interest rates. Market-based interest rate reform is intended to establish in
an orderly manner an effective pricing mechanism of bank deposit and lending
rates based on supply and demand. PBoC, the central bank, will continue to
adjust and guide interest rate liberalization to allow the market mechanism to
play an increasingly more dominant role in financial resource allocation. The
sequence of the reform is to liberalize the interest rate on foreign currency
before that on domestic currency; lending before deposit; large amount and long
term before small amount and short term. As a first step, the PBoC liberalized
the interest rates for foreign currency loans and large deposits ($3 million
and over) in September 2000. Interest rate of deposits below US$3 million
remains subject to PBoC control. In March 2002, the PBoC unified foreign
currency interest rate policies for domestic and foreign financial institutions
in China. Small foreign exchange deposits of Chinese residents with foreign
banks in China were included in the PBoC interest rate administration of small
foreign exchange deposits, so that domestic and foreign financial institutions
are treated equally with regard to the interest rate policy of foreign exchange
deposits.
As interest rate liberalization progressed, the PBoC liberalized, simplified or
eliminated 114 categories of interest rates initially under control since 1996.
At present, 34 categories of interest rates remain subject to PBoC control. The
full liberalization of interest rates on other deposit accounts, including
checking and saving accounts, is expected to take much longer. On the lending
side, market-determined interest rates on loans will first be introduced in
rural areas and then followed by rate liberalization in cities. This decision, while intended to attract more
lending funds to the rural areas, appears to be out of sync with the policy to
subsidize rural development as it makes rural borrowing more costly. China surprised global markets on April 27,
2006 by raising interest rates for the first time in 18 months to slow a debt-driven
boom that risks destabilizing the world's fastest-growing major economy. The
central bank raised its benchmark one-year lending rate to 5.85% from 5.58% but
kept its deposit rate unchanged at 2.25%, widening the profit margin for banks
which badly needs better profits. The move was billed as a measure “to further
consolidate macro-control effects, maintain a sound trend in the sustained,
fast, coordinated, and healthy development of the national economy and continue
to let economic means play a role in resources allocation and macro-control.”
But as experienced has shown in other economies, higher interest rates do not
always reduce borrowing. Often it only shifts credit allocation to distressed
borrowers who are desperate for funds even at higher cost.
Debate on Sovereign Credit
After the 1997 Asian Fiancial Crisis, China adopted a “proactive” fiscal
policy, raising large amounts of debt for public investments to drive
impressive economic growth. Ministry of Finance data showed that cumulative
long-term construction debt rose from 100 billion yuan ($12.2 billion) in 1998
to 990 billion yuan ($123.6 billion) by 2005, a ten-fold increase in 7 years.
This policy has generated heated debate among economists.
Support for sovereign debt financing is based on three arguments. Firstly, with
a ratio of 1:4 between national debt and bank loans, any rise in national debt
will result in a four-fold increase in bank loans, easing critical capital
shortage in national construction.
Secondly, since the funds raised through national debt are used to
finance public infrastructure that contributes to economic growth as measured
by GDP, rising national debt has played a significant role in China’s economic
growth without changing the national debt to GDP ratio which has remained
substantially below world standards. Since 1998, projects funded by national
debt have added about 2 percentage points per year to China’s GDP. And thirdly,
the European Union limit on debt burden for its members is 60% of GDP, and
China is far below that level at only 22%. Therefore China can safely assume a
still higher national debt level to accelerate the pace of balanced national
development, particularly in social development to boost domestic demand.
Many planners believe that sovereign debt financing is an
important tool in macro management of the economy, provided that the national
debt/GDP ratio remains below the 60% danger level and that the loan proceeds
are spent wisely. China had earlier
estimated that its debt balance in 2005 would reach 2.2 trillion yuan ($270
billion), or 16.8% of its estimated GDP.
Actual data from the Ministry of Finance showed the debt balance to be
3.26 trillion yuan ($408 billion) in 2005, nearly 18% of 2005 GDP of 18.23
trillion yuan ($2.28 trillion). By 2010, the debt balance is expected to be 4.1
trillion yuan ($510 billion), or 22.4% of its GDP; and by 2020 it will top 15.2
trillion yuan ($2000 billion), or 40% of its GDP. Past experience suggests that
these estimates are likely to be too conservative although the debt/GDP ratio
estimates may hold or even decline if the economy grows faster than the
national debt.
Other planners point out that high national debt is not a
free lunch. Questions have been raised on the appropriate use of the national
debt. To date, not much of it has been used to support social development and
environmental preservation, contributing to serious imbalances. Much of the national
debt has been used to finance local infrastructure and real estate development
projects and redundant industrial and commercial ventures that did not fit into
a coordinated national plan. Thus the high GDP growth rate has become a problem
in itself, rather than an index that reflects balance national growth.
Furthermore, the national debt to GDP ratio does not include potential
financial burdens such as contingent or implicit liabilities, e.g., the
national debt that the central government loans to municipal governments for
infrastructure construction; special national debt used for systemic bank
reform with losses from the state-owned banks’ massive non-performing loan
portfolios in their transition to commercial banks; about $60 billion borrowed
from the World Bank, Asian Development Bank, and from foreign governments in
the name of the nation but not included in the government budget; debt due to
wage payment arrears by local government and state-owned enterprises;
government grain price support loss, and a serious funding shortage in the
social security and health care obligations.
Further, most of the national debt proceeds have been used
to finance local physical infrastructure while the social infrastructure has
been largely and critically neglected in the reform process towards market
economy during the past two decades. China today exhibits all the symptoms of a
19th century boom economy in the age of industrial revolution as described by
Charles Dickens, with urban slums, migrant workers, working poor and sweatshops
at the foot of shiny new skyscrapers. Income and wealth disparity is rampant
while most of the social welfare network built through the early decades of the
socialist revolution lies in ruins. If all the government’s residual implicit
and indirect social liabilities are included, the official Chinese government
total fiscal debt is around 55% of GDP.
According to one estimate by The World Bank, Chinese government total
liability has already reached 100% of GDP. For China to reach the level of a
modern socialist society, the nation’s social liability would be more than ten
folds current levels.
For a sizable portion of the population, China’s market
reform and open to the outside policies of the past two decades have only meant
systemic exposure to unemployment, loss of health care, social security,
unequaled education opportunity for the young, below-standard housing, wages
falling behind inflation and loss of social benefits due to privatization. For everyone, rich and poor alike, a
deteriorating environment from short-sighted frenzy rate of industrialization
will take enormous sums of money and decades to restore. Economic loss from
environmental degradation and industrial pollution and accidents is reaching
crisis levels.
New Socialist Countryside Program
At long last, Chinese leaders are taking concrete steps to
reorient policy priority toward people-based social development and
environmental restoration. The focus now
is to build a New Socialist Countryside (NSC), a program launched on March 14,
2006 in the Fourth Session of the Tenth National People’s Congress, stressing
economic efficiency and social equity by narrowing the gap between rich and
poor, putting more emphasis on democratic and scientific policy making and
balanced development to ensure that reforms benefit the majority, if not all,
of the population. This paradigm shift is clear if the 11th Five-Year Plan Guidelines
are compared with the 10th. The latest version contains fewer new plans for
multi-billion-dollar construction projects, aside from critically-needed
investment to divert needed water from the country's wet south to the dry north,
or a gas pipeline from western frontiers to the coastal east. Instead, more
government funds will be used to improve standards of living for the country's
900 million rural residents, and boost sci-tech research and development. The
aim is to transform the country from a low-wage workshop of exports into a
powerhouse manufacturer of homegrown quality global brands anchored by strong domestic
demand. Infrastructure investment will be shifted from the urban areas to the
countryside, with a focus on farmland, roads, safe drinking water, methane
facilities, power-grids and telecommunications networks. Premier Wen Jaibao
pledged that rural children will receive free nine-year compulsory education of
national standard, a correct decision to break away from the market
fundamentalist policy on privatizing education in the reform era.
China's External Debt
The three main indicators for external debts for China in
2005 are all well below the internationally-accepted line of alarm reference:
20-30% for debt repayment, debt service ration 20-30% of fiscal revenue and
external debt ratio to foreign exchange income of 100-165%. Debt Service Ratio
(DSR) refers to the ratio of debt repayments to the fiscal income of the same
year, an indication of the government’s debt repayment capability. China’s debt
service ratio was 3.07% of fiscal revenue, below the 8% for international
standards. The ratio of external debt to GDP was 12.63%, and the ratio of external
debt to foreign exchange income was 33.59%. The Ministry of Finance reported
that debt balance was 3.26 trillion yuan ($407.5 billion) in 2005, nearly 18%
of 2005 GDP of 18.23 trillion yuan ($2.28 trillion). China's outstanding
foreign debts (excluding those of Hong Kong and Macao) stood at $281 billion at
the end of 2005, an increase of about $33.6 billion over the figure at the end
of the previous year, according to statistics released by the State
Administration of Foreign Exchange on March 31, 2006.
China’s government fiscal income to GDP ratio had been
erratic, being either too high or too low from year to year. In 1978, central government revenue was 31%
of GDP but only 15% of total national revenue. In 1995 it fell to 11% of
GDP and 55% of national total. But in 2004, central government fiscal revenue
rose to a slightly less than 20% of GDP and about 56% of total national fiscal
revenue. The US had federal revenue of $1.8 trillion in 2004, about 15.8% of
GDP, with a $412 billion deficit at 33% of GDP. In 1997, the Central Government
incurred a 56 billion yuan fiscal deficit at only 0.8% of GDP. By 2003-4, the
fiscal deficit increased to 320 billion yuan at 2.5% of GDP, according to
Ministry of Finance data. However, Asia Development Bank reports that China’s
fiscal revenues expanded considerably in 2004-5, rising by 21.4%, driven by
high levels of economic and trade activity and strengthened tax collection.
Fiscal expenditures rose by only 15.1%.
SOE Earnings
China’s fiscal revenue grew by 14.6% year-on-year during the
first half of 2005, to 1.64 trillion yuan ($202 billion). China’s state-owned
enterprises (SOEs), turning around from its loss-making inefficient past, had a
combined profit of 628 billion yuan ($78 billion) in 2005, more than the US General
Electric Company total earnings for the past five years at an annual average of
$15 billion. While GE shareholders received about $40 billion in dividend, at a
57% payout ratio, the Chinese government did not get a fair share dividend from
these profitable SOEs. Government administrative measures on bank lending to
overheated sector are neutralized by SOE managers who chose to finance plant
expansion with internal accruals rather than bank loans. The state as the major
shareholder of these SOEs should be paid dividends of 50% of SOE earnings or
$40 billion in 2005. The World Banks estimates the Chinese SOE profits
represented 3.3% of China’s GDP. This would be 20% of the government’s fiscal
revenue in 2005 that the government failed to collect.
Strong Fiscal Revenue
China’s fiscal revenue reached 2.64 trillion yuan ($320.7
billion) in 2004, a yearly increase of 21.6% over that in 2003, and fulfilled
112% of the budget. The fiscal revenue for central budget hit 1.51 trillion
yuan ($182.7 billion), increasing by 16.9% over the previous year. Fiscal
revenue was 109.3% of the budget. China reported a fiscal deficit of 319.177
billion yuan ($38.6 billion) in 2004.
The deficit was 653 million yuan ($79 million), less than the 319.83
billion yuan approved by the National People's Congress. Budget spending at
central and local levels totaled 1.24 trillion yuan ($153 billion) during the
period, up 15%. Central fiscal spending was up 1.5%, but central fiscal revenue
rose 10.1%, while fiscal spending by local governments jumped by 20.9% and
local fiscal revenue grew by 21%. But the Central Government paid 150.3 billion
yuan ($18.5 billion) in export tax rebates during the first six months of 2005,
104.4 billion yuan ($12.7 billion) more than the same period in 2004. National
fiscal revenue would have jumped 21.9% if central government had not paid the
increased export tax rebates, and central fiscal revenue would have been
increased 19.4%. Central government, through provincial governments, delivered
9.53 billion yuan ($1.17 billion) in direct grain production subsidies to
farmers across the country during the first half of 2005, 77% of the 13.2
billion yuan ($1.62 billion) planned for the whole year. China began to offer
subsidies directly to grain growers in 2004 in a bid to encourage farmers to
grow more grain for domestic consumption. China’s GDP reached 18.23 trillion
yuan in 2005, an increase of 9.9% over the previous year. Fiscal revenue
exceeded 3 trillion yuan in 2005, 523.2 billion yuan more than the previous
year.
Shift in Public Spending Priorities
Priorities in public spending shifted in 2005 from physical
infrastructure in urban areas to rural development, agriculture, social
security, health care and education as part of government efforts to rebalance
economic growth and social development. The 2004-5 fiscal deficit narrowed to
1.5% of GDP from 2.5% in 2003-4. However, if off-budget obligations, including
the implicit pension debt and costs related to curing nonperforming loans
(NPLs) in the banking sector were considered, the fiscal shortfall would be
much higher.
The usage efficiency of the funds raised by national debt
has been a subject of debate. Since 2000, transportation and communication
infrastructure have taken up to 40% of the total. Second are municipal
infrastructure and urban reconstruction. The last are environmental and social
welfare programs. But the national debt yield from national construction
projects has been much lower than average market return. Yet this is to be
expected as market-driven private investment tends to externalize the social
and environmental costs from their project accounting. Low internal rates of
return in national construction projects are acceptable if they contribute to
national economic growth. But the National Audit Office annual audit reported
in 2002, after auditing 37 environmental projects funded by national debt in 9
provinces to the amount of 2 billion yuan, only 9 projects finished according
to plan and met the quality requirement. A study by Professor Song Yongming at
the People’s University of China reported that “after the economic reform,
national debts were mostly used by corrupt officials in conspicuous
consumption, and not in construction expenditure as most people expected.” There were frequent reports of corrupt
officials converting projects funded by national debt into extensive illegal
bribery networks and fraud schemes. Such corruption is rooted in the absence of
separate independent supervisory and auditing authority in project management.
Yet the focus should be on rooting out corruption rather than reducing
sovereign credit for financing national construction. Unregulated market
economies have an equal if not higher penchant for fraud and corruption as
planned economies. For all governments, regardless of ideology and economic
system, anticorruption is a basic responsibility.
Monetary and Obligatory Debts
Debt comes in two forms. This is true for both private and
public debts. One is money borrowed or monetary debt which is expected to be
repaid with money. Monetary debt requires periodic interest payments for three
reasons. The first is rent for the use of the loan proceed; the second is to
preserve the purchasing power equivalence of the principal in anticipation of
future inflation and the third to compensate for risk of default. Thus interest
rate calculations are affected by these three factors. The second kind of debt
is obligatory debt which is caused by obligations yet unmet, such as payouts on
health insurance claims, social security entitlements and pension obligations. Obligatory
debt is different than monetary debt because it generally does not require
periodic interest payments but needs to be paid with equivalent purchasing
power at time of payment instead of face value at time of commitment. Thus obligatory
debt, being usually indexed against inflation, cannot be cured by inflation the
way monetary debt can.
For governments everywhere, health care, social security and
pension under-funding in both the private and public sectors are macro material
debt time bombs that have serious monetary and economic consequences. When
universal health insurance or social security/pension is privatized, any
potential of privatized insolvency adds to the public material debt. Sovereign governments seldom default on
either monetary or material debt denominated in its own fiat currency, as they
can usually issue more fiat money to meet such debt obligations, provided they
are prepared to accept the monetary and economic consequences. Such
consequences take the form of domestic inflation and a fall in credit ratings
of sovereign debts, both of which cause interest rates to rise. Holders of
sovereign debt denominated in domestic currencies seldom face default risks,
only inflation risks. The real systemic danger is of course hyperinflation
which can take on a destructive path of its own. Hyperinflation can occur when governments
issue debt in excess of economic expansion, causing the credit rating of
government debt to fall substantially below those of other borrowers. A healthy
debt market is one in which government debt is at the top of the credit rating
structure. Material debt, unlike monetary debt, can accumulate at a scale and
speed that render normal monetary structure inoperative. Government default on
material debt has direct and immediate economic consequences the can spill over
to the political arena.
The Risk of Foreign Currency Debts
When sovereign governments take on debts denominated in
foreign currencies, the risk of default becomes material, as no government can
issue foreign currency and must earn it through taxes on export to repay
foreign currency loans. When a sovereign government buys foreign currency with
its domestic currency in the exchange market, it is essentially selling claims
on its future exports. In a global economy of overcapacity, for an economy that
incurs recurring trade deficits, the foreign currency debt can only be paid
with domestic austerity, causing a downward economic spiral. Such disasters
have been commonplace all through the developing world in the past two decades
and are continuing today. When governments adopt freely convertible currency
regimes, the exchange rates of their currencies are subject to market forces
which can often be manipulated by speculators such as hedge funds which seek to
squeeze profit from discrepancies between current exchange rates and the
fundamental economic value of currencies. With an exchange rate regime exposed
to market forces, sovereign debt denominated in domestic fiat currencies will
be subject to speculative forces beyond the control of the issuing government.
This leads directly to a loss of sovereign authority on monetary and fiscal
policies and places restriction on the option to use sovereign credit for
domestic development. The sovereign
government that faces foreign currency debt default will be put under financial
house arrest in a debt prison in its own country by “conditionalities” imposed
by the International Monetary Fund which operates as a vicious loan shark
against the indebted government.
The Mundell-Fleming thesis, for which Robert Mundell won the
1999 Nobel Prize, states that in international finance, a government has the
choice among (1) stable exchange rates, (2) international capital mobility and
(3) domestic policy autonomy (full employment, interest rate policies,
counter-cyclical fiscal spending, etc). With unregulated global financial
markets, a government can have only two of the three options. When spending for
domestic development is financed by not by sovereign credit denominated in
local currencies, but by sovereign debt denominated in foreign currencies, a
government faces risk of loss of financial and monetary sovereignty. Even if
sovereign debts are issued only in domestic currencies, cross-border capital
mobility will expose domestic currencies to speculative attacks. It is becoming increasingly obvious that
restriction on international capital mobility is the least costly of the three
options. Through dollar hegemony, the
United States is the only country that can defy the Mundell-Fleming thesis,
because the dollar, a reserve currency for international trade and finance, can
be printed at will by the US central bank without penalty.
The Non-Bond Debt Market
Monetary debts are generally tradable, intermediated through
debt markets which consist of bond and non-bond markets. The non-bond market is
relatively new and fall generally within the field of structured finance – the
securitization of debt through which packaged debts are unbundled into tranches
of varying risk to be marketed at varying rates of return to investors with
varying appetite for risk. Along with
debt securitization grew a market for financial derivatives, initially
developed as a hedging venue against risk, but soon developed into a profit
center that exploits the ballooning of risk. This market is not well understood
by either market participants or regulators and data on it are imperfect. (See: Dangers of Derivatives)
Timothy F. Geithner, President and CEO of the NY Federal
Reserve Bank, warned in a speech: Risk Management Challenges in the U.S.
Financial System, before the Global Association of Risk Professionals (GARP)
7th Annual Risk Management Convention & Exhibition in New York City on February
28, 2006 that the scale of the over-the-counter derivatives markets is dangerously
large. “Although the notional total value of these contracts, now approaching
$300 trillion, is not a particularly useful measure of the underlying economic
exposure at stake, the size of gross exposures and the extraordinarily large
number of contracts suggest the scale of the unwinding challenge the market
would confront in the event of the exit of a major counterparty. The process of
closing out those positions and replacing them could add stress to markets and
possibly intensify the direct damage caused by exposure to the exiting
institution.”
Geithner observed that credit derivatives, where the gaps in
the infrastructure and risk management systems are most conspicuous, are less
than 10% of the total OTC derivatives universe, but are growing rapidly. Large
notional values are written on a much smaller base of underlying debt issuance.
The same names show up in multiple types of positions—singles-name, index and structured
products. These create the potential for squeezes in cash markets and greater
volatility across instruments in the event of a default, magnifying the risk of
adverse market dynamics.
The net credit exposures in OTC derivatives, after
accounting for collateral, are a small fraction of the gross notional values.
The ten largest U.S. bank holding companies, for example, report about $600
billion of potential credit exposure from their entire derivatives positions,
the total gross notional values of which are about $95 trillion. That leaves
more than $200 trillion of notional value to be reckon with outside the banking
sector. This $600 billion “credit equivalent amount” exposure faced by banks is
approximately 175% of tier-one capital, about 15% higher relative to capital
than five years ago. This measure of the underlying credit exposure in OTC
derivatives positions is roughly a fifth of the aggregate total credit exposure
of the largest bank holding companies. This is a relatively conservative
measure of the credit risk in total derivatives positions, but, for credit
derivatives and some other instruments, it still may not adequately capture the
scale of losses in the event of default in the underlying credits or the
consequences of a prolonged disruption to market liquidity. The complexity of
many new instruments and the relative immaturity of the various approaches used
to measure the risks in those exposures magnify the uncertainty involved.
Geithner allowed that internal risk management systems have
improved substantially since the mid-1990s, but most firms still face
considerable challenges in aggregating exposures across the firm, capturing
concentrations in exposures to credit and other risks, and producing stress
testing and scenario analysis on a fully integrated picture of exposures
generated across their increasingly diverse array of activities. The greater
diversity of institutions that now provide demand for credit risk, or are
willing to hold credit risk, should make credit markets more liquid and
resilient than would be the case if credit risk was still held predominantly by
banks or by a smaller number of more uniform institutions, with less capacity
to hedge those exposures. However, the financial system still faces
considerable uncertainty about how market liquidity will behave in the context
of a major deterioration in credit conditions or a sharp increase in volatility
in equity and credit spreads, and this uncertainty is hard to quantify and
therefore hard to integrate into the risk management process.
The apparent increase in the scale of demand for exposure to
credit risk relative to the growth in supply of credit has contributed to a
substantial reduction in credit spreads and to some erosion in credit terms.
Banks and dealers have reported pressure to reduce initial margin levels. The
scale of leverage in some transactions is reported to have risen. The spread of
portfolio-based margining creates the potential for greater overall leverage in
the financial system, and the substantial variance in margin required by
different dealers for similar portfolios suggests a wide diversity of views on
how to measure the economic exposure.
Although US banks hold a substantially smaller share of the
overall credit risk in the system than they did twenty years ago, this shift
understates the importance of the role they play in the underwriting,
distribution, trading and market making of credit related assets, and it
understates the importance of earnings derived from these activities to overall
profitability. Major banks and dealers at the core of these markets generate
both short- and longer-term credit and market risk exposures from a number of
sources and activities, including trading positions, loan commitments that
support securities issuance, and warehousing positions in advance of packaging
and distributing them. Retained interests associated with securitization
transactions are substantial relative to capital of the largest firms. And the
importance of securitization for the firms—both from a funding and revenue
generation standpoint—provides an incentive for them to support investors in
these products in ways that may go beyond contractual obligations.
The post-trade processing and settlement infrastructure,
particularly in credit derivatives, is still quite weak relative to the
significance of these markets, although the major dealers and buy-side
investors are making a substantial effort to address these problems. The total
stock of unconfirmed trades is large and until recently was growing
considerably faster than the total volume of new trades. The time between trade
and confirmation is still quite long for a large share of the transactions. The
share of trades done on the available automated platforms is still
substantially short of what is possible. Until the adoption of a new protocol
last fall, firms were typically assigning trades without the knowledge or
consent of the original counterparties. Nostro breaks, which are errors in
payments discovered by counterparties at the time of the quarterly flows, rose
to a significant share of total trades. Efforts to standardize documentation
and provide automated confirmation services have lagged behind product
development and growth in volume. Although the risk controls seem to have done
a pretty good job of capturing the economic terms of the trades, the assignment
problems create uncertainty about the actual size of exposures to individual
counterparties that could exacerbate market liquidity problems in the event of
stress.
Chinese commercial banks, in joining the game of
international competition under WTO rules, will be forced to participate in the
credit derivatives market which are time bombs of massive systemic financial
destruction.
Next: Development Financing and Urbanization
|